![Goods (economics)](https://www.english.nina.az/wikipedia/image/aHR0cHM6Ly91cGxvYWQud2lraW1lZGlhLm9yZy93aWtpcGVkaWEvY29tbW9ucy90aHVtYi9mL2Y1L01lZGlxX1N2ZXJpZ2VfS3VuZ3NiYWNrYV93YXJlaG91c2UuanBnLzE2MDBweC1NZWRpcV9TdmVyaWdlX0t1bmdzYmFja2Ffd2FyZWhvdXNlLmpwZw==.jpg )
In economics, goods are anything that is good, in the sense of providing welfare or utility to someone. Goods can be contrasted with bads, i.e. things that provide negative value for users, like chores or waste. A bad lowers a consumer's overall welfare.
![image](https://www.english.nina.az/wikipedia/image/aHR0cHM6Ly93d3cuZW5nbGlzaC5uaW5hLmF6L3dpa2lwZWRpYS9pbWFnZS9hSFIwY0hNNkx5OTFjR3h2WVdRdWQybHJhVzFsWkdsaExtOXlaeTkzYVd0cGNHVmthV0V2WTI5dGJXOXVjeTkwYUhWdFlpOW1MMlkxTDAxbFpHbHhYMU4yWlhKcFoyVmZTM1Z1WjNOaVlXTnJZVjkzWVhKbGFHOTFjMlV1YW5Cbkx6SXlNSEI0TFUxbFpHbHhYMU4yWlhKcFoyVmZTM1Z1WjNOaVlXTnJZVjkzWVhKbGFHOTFjMlV1YW5Cbi5qcGc=.jpg)
Economics focuses on the study of economic goods, i.e. goods that are scarce; in other words, producing the good requires expending effort or resources. Economic goods contrast with free goods such as air, for which there is an unlimited supply.
Utility and characteristics of goods
The change in utility (pleasure or satisfaction) gained by consuming one unit of a good is called its marginal utility. Goods are commonly considered to have diminishing marginal utility, which means that consuming more gives less utility per amount consumed. Some things are useful, but not scarce enough to have monetary value, such as the Earth's atmosphere; these are referred to as free goods.
Final goods are items that are ultimately consumed, rather than used in the production of another good. For example, a microwave oven or a bicycle that is sold to a consumer is a final good or consumer good, but the components that are sold to be used in those goods are intermediate goods. For example, textiles or transistors can be used to make some further goods.
Commercial goods are construed as tangible products that are manufactured and then made available for supply to be used in an industry of commerce. Commercial goods could be tractors, commercial vehicles, mobile structures, airplanes, and even roofing materials. Commercial and personal goods as categories are very broad and cover almost everything a person sees from the time they wake up in their home, on their commute to work to their arrival at the workplace.
Commodities may be used as a synonym for economic goods but often refer to marketable raw materials and primary products.
Although common goods are tangible, certain classes of goods, such as information, only take intangible forms. For example, among other goods an apple is a tangible object, while news belongs to an intangible class of goods and can be perceived only by means of an instrument such as printers or television.
Types of goods
![image](https://www.english.nina.az/wikipedia/image/aHR0cHM6Ly93d3cuZW5nbGlzaC5uaW5hLmF6L3dpa2lwZWRpYS9pbWFnZS9hSFIwY0hNNkx5OTFjR3h2WVdRdWQybHJhVzFsWkdsaExtOXlaeTkzYVd0cGNHVmthV0V2WTI5dGJXOXVjeTkwYUhWdFlpOW1MMlkxTDFSNWNHVnpYMjltWDJkdmIyUnpMbk4yWnk4eU9UWndlQzFVZVhCbGMxOXZabDluYjI5a2N5NXpkbWN1Y0c1bi5wbmc=.png)
Goods' diversity allows for their classification into different categories based on distinctive characteristics, such as tangibility and (ordinal) relative elasticity. A tangible good like an apple differs from an intangible good like information due to the impossibility of a person to physically hold the latter, whereas the former occupies physical space. Intangible goods differ from services in that final (intangible) goods are transferable and can be traded, whereas a service cannot.
Price elasticity also differentiates types of goods. An elastic good is one for which there is a relatively large change in quantity due to a relatively small change in price, and therefore is likely to be part of a family of substitute goods; for example, as pen prices rise, consumers might buy more pencils instead. An inelastic good is one for which there are few or no substitutes, such as tickets to major sporting events, original works by famous artists, and prescription medicine such as insulin. Complementary goods are generally more inelastic than goods in a family of substitutes. For example, if a rise in the price of beef results in a decrease in the quantity of beef demanded, it is likely that the quantity of hamburger buns demanded will also drop, despite no change in buns' prices. This is because hamburger buns and beef (in Western culture) are complementary goods. Goods considered complements or substitutes are relative associations and should not be understood in a vacuum. The degree to which a good is a substitute or a complement depends on its relationship to other goods, rather than an intrinsic characteristic, and can be measured as cross elasticity of demand by employing statistical techniques such as covariance and correlation.
Bads
A bad is the opposite of a good, because its consumption or presence lowers the customer's utility. With goods, a two-party transaction results in the exchange of money for some object, as when money is exchanged for a car. With a bad, however, both money and the object in question go the same direction, as when a household gives up both money and garbage to a waste collector, meaning the garbage has a negative price (as the waste collector is receiving both garbage and money, thus paying a negative amount for the garbage).
Goods classified by exclusivity and competitiveness
Fourfold model of goods
Goods can be classified based on their degree of excludability and rivalry (competitiveness). Considering excludability can be measured on a continuous scale, some goods would not be able to fall into one of the four common categories used.
There are four types of goods based on the characteristics of rival in consumption and excludability: Public Goods, Private Goods, Common Resources, and Club Goods. These four types plus examples for anti-rivalry appear in the accompanying table.
Excludable | Non-excludable | |
---|---|---|
Rivalrous | Private goods eg. food, clothing, parking spaces | Common-pool resources eg. fish stocks, timber |
Non-rivalrous | Club goods eg. cinemas, software, private parks | Public goods eg. free-to-air television, air, national defense |
Public goods
Goods that are both non-rival and non-excludable are called public goods. In many cases, renewable resources, such as land, are common commodities but some of them are contained in public goods. Public goods are non-exclusive and non-competitive, meaning that individuals cannot be stopped from using them and anyone can consume this good without hindering the ability of others to consume them. Examples in addition to the ones in the matrix are national parks, or firework displays. It is generally accepted by mainstream economists that the market mechanism will under-provide public goods, so these goods have to be produced by other means, including government provision. Public goods can also suffer from the Free-Rider problem.
Private goods
Private goods are excludable goods, which prevent other consumers from consuming them. Private goods are also rivalrous because one good in private ownership cannot be used by someone else. That is to say, consuming some goods will deprive another consumer of the ability to consume the goods. Private goods are the most common type of goods. They include what you have to get from the store. For examples food, clothing, cars, parking spaces, etc. An individual who consumes an apple denies another individual from consuming the same one. It is excludable because consumption is only offered to those willing to pay the price.
Common-pool resources
Common-pool resources are rival in consumption and non-excludable. An example is that of fisheries, which harvest fish from a shared common resource pool of fish stock. Fish caught by one group of fishermen are no longer accessible to another group, thus being rivalrous. However, oftentimes, due to an absence of well-defined property rights, it is difficult to restrict access to fishermen who may overfish.
Club goods
Club goods are excludable but not rivalrous in the consumption. That is, not everyone can use the good, but when one individual has claim to use it, they do not reduce the amount or the ability for others to consume the good. By joining a specific club or organization we can obtain club goods; As a result, some people are excluded because they are not members. Examples in addition to the ones in the matrix are cable television, golf courses, and any merchandise provided to club members. A large television service provider would already have infrastructure in place which would allow for the addition of new customers without infringing on existing customers viewing abilities. This would also mean that marginal cost would be close to zero, which satisfies the criteria for a good to be considered non-rival. However, access to cable TV services is only available to consumers willing to pay the price, demonstrating the excludability aspect.
Economists set these categories for these goods and their impact on consumers. The government is usually responsible for public goods and common goods, and enterprises are generally responsible for the production of private and club goods, although this is not always the case.
History of the fourfold model of goods
In 1977, Nobel winner Elinor Ostrom and her husband Vincent Ostrom proposed additional modifications to the existing classification of goods so to identify fundamental differences that affect the incentives facing individuals. Their definitions are presented on the matrix.
Elinor Ostrom proposed additional modifications to the classification of goods to identify fundamental differences that affect the incentives facing individuals
- Replacing the term "rivalry of consumption" with "subtractability of use".
- Conceptualizing subtractability of use and excludability to vary from low to high rather than characterizing them as either present or absent.
- Overtly adding a very important fourth type of good—common-pool resources—that shares the attribute of subtractability with private goods and difficulty of exclusion with public goods. Forests, water systems, fisheries, and the global atmosphere are all common-pool resources of immense importance for the survival of humans on this earth.
- Changing the name of a "club" good to a "toll" good since goods that share these characteristics are provided by small scale public as well as private associations.
Expansion of Fourfold model: Anti-rivalrous
Consumption can be extended to include "Anti-rivalrous" consumption.
Excludable | ||
---|---|---|
yes | no | |
Rivalrous | Private Good | Common-pool good |
Non-rivalrous | Club / toll Good | Public Good |
Anti-rivalrous | "network" good, e.g., data on the internet; good that improves public health | "symbiotic" good, e.g., language |
Expansion of Fourfold model: Semi-Excludable
The additional definition matrix shows the four common categories alongside providing some examples of fully excludable goods, Semi-excludable goods and fully non-excludeable goods. Semi-excludable goods can be considered goods or services that a mostly successful in excluding non-paying customer, but are still able to be consumed by non-paying consumers. An example of this is movies, books or video games that could be easily pirated and shared for free.
Fully Excludable | Semi-Excludable | Fully Non-Excludable | |
---|---|---|---|
Rivalrous | Private Goods food, clothing, cars, parking spaces | Piracy of copyrighted goods like movies, books, video games | Common-pool Resources fish, timber, coal, free public transport |
Non-Rivalrous | Club Goods cinemas, private parks, television, public transport | Sharing pay television or streaming subscriptions to more users than what is being paid for | Public Goods free-to-air, air, national defense, free and open-source software |
Trading of goods
Goods are capable of being physically delivered to a consumer. Goods that are economic intangibles can only be stored, delivered, and consumed by means of media.
Goods, both tangibles and intangibles, may involve the transfer of product ownership to the consumer. Services do not normally involve transfer of ownership of the service itself, but may involve transfer of ownership of goods developed or marketed by a service provider in the course of the service. For example, sale of storage related goods, which could consist of storage sheds, storage containers, storage buildings as tangibles or storage supplies such as boxes, bubble wrap, tape, bags and the like which are consumables, or distributing electricity among consumers is a service provided by an electric utility company. This service can only be experienced through the consumption of electrical energy, which is available in a variety of voltages and, in this case, is the economic goods produced by the electric utility company. While the service (namely, distribution of electrical energy) is a process that remains in its entirety in the ownership of the electric service provider, the goods (namely, electric energy) is the object of ownership transfer. The consumer becomes an electric energy owner by purchase and may use it for any lawful purposes just like any other goods.
See also
- Bad (economics)
- Commodification
- Fast-moving consumer goods
- Final goods
- Goods and services
- Intangible asset
- Intangible good
- List of economics topics
- Property
- Service (economics)
Notes
- Alan V. Deardorff, 2006. Terms Of Trade: Glossary of International Economics, World Scientific. Online version: Deardorffs' Glossary of International Economics, "good" Archived 2013-03-18 at the Wayback Machine and "service". Archived 2017-07-01 at the Wayback Machine
- Harper, Douglas. "goods". Online Etymology Dictionary.
- Dwivedi, D. N. (2016). Microeconomics: Theory and Applications. Vikas Publishing House PVT LTD. p. 133. ISBN 978-93259-8670-1.
- Samuelson, P. Anthony., Samuelson, W. (1980). Economics. 11th ed. / New York: McGraw-Hill.
- "Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility". Corporate Finance Institute. 2023-11-22. Retrieved 2024-12-20.
- Steedman, Ian (1989). "Free Goods". General Equilibrium. London: Palgrave Macmillan UK. p. 158–161. doi:10.1007/978-1-349-19802-3_17. ISBN 978-0-333-49525-4.
- Alan V. Deardorff, 2006, Deardorffs' Glossary of International Economics "commodity". Archived 2007-12-12 at the Wayback Machine
- Quotation from Murray Milgate, 2008, "Goods and Commodities". In: Palgrave Macmillan (eds) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave, Macmillan, London., in referencing an influential parallel definition of 'goods' by Alfred Marshall, 1891. Principles of Economics,1961, 9th ed. Section I, page 54, Macmillan.
- Varian, Hal R. (2006). Intermediate Microeconomics. London: W.W. Norton & Company. p. 41.
- Mankiw, N. Gregory. (2012). Principles of microeconomics (6th ed.). Mason, OH: South-Western Cengage Learning. ISBN 978-0-538-45304-2. OCLC 742415439.
- Pekka Nikander; Ville Eloranta; Kimmo Karhu; Kari Hiekkanen (2 June 2020), Digitalisation, anti-rival compensation and governance: Need for experiments, Wikidata Q106510738.
- Hubbard, R.G; Garnett, A; Lewis, P; O'Brien, A (2018). Essentials of Economics Ebook. Australia: Pearson Education Australia. p. 351. ISBN 9781488617003.
- Perloff, J (2018). Microeconomics, Global Edition (Eighth ed.). Pearson Education Limited. pp. 635–636. ISBN 9781292215693.
- Perloff, J (2018). Microeconomics, Global Edition (Eighth ed.). Pearson Education Limited. p. 637. ISBN 9781292215693.
- Ostrom, E. (2010). Beyond Markets and States : Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems. American Economic Review, 100(June), 408–444. https://doi.org/10.1080/19186444.2010.11658229
- Elinor, Ostrom (2005). Understanding Institutional Diversity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
References
- Bannock, Graham et al. (1997). Dictionary of Economics, Penguin Books.
- Milgate, Murray (1987), "goods and commodities," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 2, pp. 546–48. Includes historical and contemporary uses of the terms in economics.
- Vuaridel, R. (1968). Une définition des biens économiques. (A definition of economic goods). L'Année sociologique (1940/1948-), 19, 133–170. JSTOR 27887387
External links
Media related to Goods (economics) at Wikimedia Commons
In economics goods are anything that is good in the sense of providing welfare or utility to someone Goods can be contrasted with bads i e things that provide negative value for users like chores or waste A bad lowers a consumer s overall welfare Tangible goods stacked in a warehouse Economics focuses on the study of economic goods i e goods that are scarce in other words producing the good requires expending effort or resources Economic goods contrast with free goods such as air for which there is an unlimited supply Utility and characteristics of goodsThe change in utility pleasure or satisfaction gained by consuming one unit of a good is called its marginal utility Goods are commonly considered to have diminishing marginal utility which means that consuming more gives less utility per amount consumed Some things are useful but not scarce enough to have monetary value such as the Earth s atmosphere these are referred to as free goods Final goods are items that are ultimately consumed rather than used in the production of another good For example a microwave oven or a bicycle that is sold to a consumer is a final good or consumer good but the components that are sold to be used in those goods are intermediate goods For example textiles or transistors can be used to make some further goods Commercial goods are construed as tangible products that are manufactured and then made available for supply to be used in an industry of commerce Commercial goods could be tractors commercial vehicles mobile structures airplanes and even roofing materials Commercial and personal goods as categories are very broad and cover almost everything a person sees from the time they wake up in their home on their commute to work to their arrival at the workplace Commodities may be used as a synonym for economic goods but often refer to marketable raw materials and primary products Although common goods are tangible certain classes of goods such as information only take intangible forms For example among other goods an apple is a tangible object while news belongs to an intangible class of goods and can be perceived only by means of an instrument such as printers or television Types of goodsTypes of goods in economics Goods diversity allows for their classification into different categories based on distinctive characteristics such as tangibility and ordinal relative elasticity A tangible good like an apple differs from an intangible good like information due to the impossibility of a person to physically hold the latter whereas the former occupies physical space Intangible goods differ from services in that final intangible goods are transferable and can be traded whereas a service cannot Price elasticity also differentiates types of goods An elastic good is one for which there is a relatively large change in quantity due to a relatively small change in price and therefore is likely to be part of a family of substitute goods for example as pen prices rise consumers might buy more pencils instead An inelastic good is one for which there are few or no substitutes such as tickets to major sporting events original works by famous artists and prescription medicine such as insulin Complementary goods are generally more inelastic than goods in a family of substitutes For example if a rise in the price of beef results in a decrease in the quantity of beef demanded it is likely that the quantity of hamburger buns demanded will also drop despite no change in buns prices This is because hamburger buns and beef in Western culture are complementary goods Goods considered complements or substitutes are relative associations and should not be understood in a vacuum The degree to which a good is a substitute or a complement depends on its relationship to other goods rather than an intrinsic characteristic and can be measured as cross elasticity of demand by employing statistical techniques such as covariance and correlation Bads A bad is the opposite of a good because its consumption or presence lowers the customer s utility With goods a two party transaction results in the exchange of money for some object as when money is exchanged for a car With a bad however both money and the object in question go the same direction as when a household gives up both money and garbage to a waste collector meaning the garbage has a negative price as the waste collector is receiving both garbage and money thus paying a negative amount for the garbage Goods classified by exclusivity and competitivenessFourfold model of goods Goods can be classified based on their degree of excludability and rivalry competitiveness Considering excludability can be measured on a continuous scale some goods would not be able to fall into one of the four common categories used There are four types of goods based on the characteristics of rival in consumption and excludability Public Goods Private Goods Common Resources and Club Goods These four types plus examples for anti rivalry appear in the accompanying table Excludable Non excludableRivalrous Private goods eg food clothing parking spaces Common pool resources eg fish stocks timberNon rivalrous Club goods eg cinemas software private parks Public goods eg free to air television air national defensePublic goods Goods that are both non rival and non excludable are called public goods In many cases renewable resources such as land are common commodities but some of them are contained in public goods Public goods are non exclusive and non competitive meaning that individuals cannot be stopped from using them and anyone can consume this good without hindering the ability of others to consume them Examples in addition to the ones in the matrix are national parks or firework displays It is generally accepted by mainstream economists that the market mechanism will under provide public goods so these goods have to be produced by other means including government provision Public goods can also suffer from the Free Rider problem Private goods Private goods are excludable goods which prevent other consumers from consuming them Private goods are also rivalrous because one good in private ownership cannot be used by someone else That is to say consuming some goods will deprive another consumer of the ability to consume the goods Private goods are the most common type of goods They include what you have to get from the store For examples food clothing cars parking spaces etc An individual who consumes an apple denies another individual from consuming the same one It is excludable because consumption is only offered to those willing to pay the price Common pool resources Common pool resources are rival in consumption and non excludable An example is that of fisheries which harvest fish from a shared common resource pool of fish stock Fish caught by one group of fishermen are no longer accessible to another group thus being rivalrous However oftentimes due to an absence of well defined property rights it is difficult to restrict access to fishermen who may overfish Club goods Club goods are excludable but not rivalrous in the consumption That is not everyone can use the good but when one individual has claim to use it they do not reduce the amount or the ability for others to consume the good By joining a specific club or organization we can obtain club goods As a result some people are excluded because they are not members Examples in addition to the ones in the matrix are cable television golf courses and any merchandise provided to club members A large television service provider would already have infrastructure in place which would allow for the addition of new customers without infringing on existing customers viewing abilities This would also mean that marginal cost would be close to zero which satisfies the criteria for a good to be considered non rival However access to cable TV services is only available to consumers willing to pay the price demonstrating the excludability aspect Economists set these categories for these goods and their impact on consumers The government is usually responsible for public goods and common goods and enterprises are generally responsible for the production of private and club goods although this is not always the case History of the fourfold model of goods In 1977 Nobel winner Elinor Ostrom and her husband Vincent Ostrom proposed additional modifications to the existing classification of goods so to identify fundamental differences that affect the incentives facing individuals Their definitions are presented on the matrix Elinor Ostrom proposed additional modifications to the classification of goods to identify fundamental differences that affect the incentives facing individuals Replacing the term rivalry of consumption with subtractability of use Conceptualizing subtractability of use and excludability to vary from low to high rather than characterizing them as either present or absent Overtly adding a very important fourth type of good common pool resources that shares the attribute of subtractability with private goods and difficulty of exclusion with public goods Forests water systems fisheries and the global atmosphere are all common pool resources of immense importance for the survival of humans on this earth Changing the name of a club good to a toll good since goods that share these characteristics are provided by small scale public as well as private associations Expansion of Fourfold model Anti rivalrous Consumption can be extended to include Anti rivalrous consumption Types of goods based on consumption and excludability Excludableyes noRivalrous Private Good Common pool goodNon rivalrous Club toll Good Public GoodAnti rivalrous network good e g data on the internet good that improves public health symbiotic good e g languageExpansion of Fourfold model Semi Excludable The additional definition matrix shows the four common categories alongside providing some examples of fully excludable goods Semi excludable goods and fully non excludeable goods Semi excludable goods can be considered goods or services that a mostly successful in excluding non paying customer but are still able to be consumed by non paying consumers An example of this is movies books or video games that could be easily pirated and shared for free Fully Excludable Semi Excludable Fully Non ExcludableRivalrous Private Goods food clothing cars parking spaces Piracy of copyrighted goods like movies books video games Common pool Resources fish timber coal free public transportNon Rivalrous Club Goods cinemas private parks television public transport Sharing pay television or streaming subscriptions to more users than what is being paid for Public Goods free to air air national defense free and open source softwareTrading of goodsGoods are capable of being physically delivered to a consumer Goods that are economic intangibles can only be stored delivered and consumed by means of media Goods both tangibles and intangibles may involve the transfer of product ownership to the consumer Services do not normally involve transfer of ownership of the service itself but may involve transfer of ownership of goods developed or marketed by a service provider in the course of the service For example sale of storage related goods which could consist of storage sheds storage containers storage buildings as tangibles or storage supplies such as boxes bubble wrap tape bags and the like which are consumables or distributing electricity among consumers is a service provided by an electric utility company This service can only be experienced through the consumption of electrical energy which is available in a variety of voltages and in this case is the economic goods produced by the electric utility company While the service namely distribution of electrical energy is a process that remains in its entirety in the ownership of the electric service provider the goods namely electric energy is the object of ownership transfer The consumer becomes an electric energy owner by purchase and may use it for any lawful purposes just like any other goods See alsoBad economics Commodification Fast moving consumer goods Final goods Goods and services Intangible asset Intangible good List of economics topics Property Tangible property Service economics NotesAlan V Deardorff 2006 Terms Of Trade Glossary of International Economics World Scientific Online version Deardorffs Glossary of International Economics good Archived 2013 03 18 at the Wayback Machine and service Archived 2017 07 01 at the Wayback Machine Harper Douglas goods Online Etymology Dictionary Dwivedi D N 2016 Microeconomics Theory and Applications Vikas Publishing House PVT LTD p 133 ISBN 978 93259 8670 1 Samuelson P Anthony Samuelson W 1980 Economics 11th ed New York McGraw Hill Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility Corporate Finance Institute 2023 11 22 Retrieved 2024 12 20 Steedman Ian 1989 Free Goods General Equilibrium London Palgrave Macmillan UK p 158 161 doi 10 1007 978 1 349 19802 3 17 ISBN 978 0 333 49525 4 Alan V Deardorff 2006 Deardorffs Glossary of International Economics commodity Archived 2007 12 12 at the Wayback Machine Quotation from Murray Milgate 2008 Goods and Commodities In Palgrave Macmillan eds The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Palgrave Macmillan London in referencing an influential parallel definition of goods by Alfred Marshall 1891 Principles of Economics 1961 9th ed Section I page 54 Macmillan Varian Hal R 2006 Intermediate Microeconomics London W W Norton amp Company p 41 Mankiw N Gregory 2012 Principles of microeconomics 6th ed Mason OH South Western Cengage Learning ISBN 978 0 538 45304 2 OCLC 742415439 Pekka Nikander Ville Eloranta Kimmo Karhu Kari Hiekkanen 2 June 2020 Digitalisation anti rival compensation and governance Need for experiments Wikidata Q106510738 Hubbard R G Garnett A Lewis P O Brien A 2018 Essentials of Economics Ebook Australia Pearson Education Australia p 351 ISBN 9781488617003 Perloff J 2018 Microeconomics Global Edition Eighth ed Pearson Education Limited pp 635 636 ISBN 9781292215693 Perloff J 2018 Microeconomics Global Edition Eighth ed Pearson Education Limited p 637 ISBN 9781292215693 Ostrom E 2010 Beyond Markets and States Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems American Economic Review 100 June 408 444 https doi org 10 1080 19186444 2010 11658229 Elinor Ostrom 2005 Understanding Institutional Diversity Princeton NJ Princeton University Press ReferencesBannock Graham et al 1997 Dictionary of Economics Penguin Books Milgate Murray 1987 goods and commodities The New Palgrave A Dictionary of Economics v 2 pp 546 48 Includes historical and contemporary uses of the terms in economics Vuaridel R 1968 Une definition des biens economiques A definition of economic goods L Annee sociologique 1940 1948 19 133 170 JSTOR 27887387External linksMedia related to Goods economics at Wikimedia Commons