This article includes a list of general references, but it lacks sufficient corresponding inline citations.(October 2024) |
A royalty payment is a payment made by one party to another that owns a particular asset, for the right to ongoing use of that asset. Royalties are typically agreed upon as a percentage of gross or net revenues derived from the use of an asset or a fixed price per unit sold of an item of such, but there are also other modes and metrics of compensation. A royalty interest is the right to collect a stream of future royalty payments.
A license agreement defines the terms under which a resource or property are licensed by one party to another, either without restriction or subject to a limitation on term, business or geographic territory, type of product, etc. License agreements can be regulated, particularly where a government is the resource owner, or they can be private contracts that follow a general structure. However, certain types of franchise agreements have comparable provisions.[clarification needed]
Non-renewable resources
A landowner with petroleum or mineral rights to their property may license those rights to another party. In exchange for allowing the other party to extract the resources, the landowner receives either a resource rent, or a "royalty payment" based on the value of the resources sold. When a government owns the resource, the transaction often has to follow legal and regulatory requirements.[citation needed]
In the United States, fee simple ownership of mineral rights is possible and payments of royalties to private citizens occurs quite often. Local taxing authorities may impose a severance tax on the unrenewable natural resources extracted or severed from within their authority. The Federal Government receives royalties on production on federal lands, managed by the Bureau of Ocean Energy Management, Regulation and Enforcement, formerly the Minerals Management Service.[citation needed]
An example from Canada's northern territories is the federal Frontier Lands Petroleum Royalty Regulations. The royalty rate starts at 1% of gross revenues of the first 18 months of commercial production and increases by 1% every 18 months to a maximum of 5% until initial costs have been recovered, at which point the royalty rate is set at 5% of gross revenues or 30% of net revenues. In this manner risks and profits are shared between the government of Canada (as resource owner) and the petroleum developer. This attractive royalty rate is intended to encourage oil and gas exploration in the remote Canadian frontier lands where costs and risks are higher than other locations.
In many jurisdictions in North America, oil and gas royalty interests are considered real property under the NAICS classification code and qualify for a 1031 like-kind exchange.
Oil and gas royalties are paid as a set percentage on all revenue, less any deductions that may be taken by the well operator as specifically noted in the lease agreement. The revenue decimal, or royalty interest that a mineral owner receives, is calculated as a function of the percentage of the total drilling unit to which a specific owner holds the mineral interest, the royalty rate defined in that owner's mineral lease, and any tract participation factors applied to the specific tracts owned.
As a standard example, for every $100 bbl of oil sold on a U.S. federal well with a 25% royalty, the U.S. government receives $25. The U.S. government does not pay and will only collect revenues. All risk and liability lie upon the operator of the well.
Royalties in the lumber industry are called "stumpage".
Wind Royalties
Landowners who host wind turbines are often paid wind royalties, and those nearby may be paid nuisance payments to compensate for noise and flicker effects. Wind royalties are usually paid quarterly, semi-annually, or annually, and the royalty can be a flat rate or variable payment based on production or a combination of both.
Unlike oil and gas royalties, which typically decline over time, wind royalties often have an escalation clause, making them more valuable over time. Because there is not yet a robust body of law regarding wind royalties, the legal implications of severing wind rights are still unknown. Several states, including Colorado, Kansas, Oklahoma, North Dakota, South Dakota, Nebraska, Montana, and Wyoming, have enacted anti-severance statutes, preventing the wind estate from being severed from the surface. Regardless, the ownership of wind royalties and compensation payments can be transferred from the landowner to another party. Over time, wind royalties will be fractioned similarly to oil and gas royalties.
Patents
An intangible asset such as a patent right gives the owner an exclusive right to prevent others from practicing the patented technology in the country issuing the patent for the term of the patent. The right may be enforced in a lawsuit for monetary damages and/or imprisonment for violation on the patent. In accordance with a patent license, royalties are paid to the patent owner in exchange for the right to practice one or more of the basic patent rights: to manufacture, to use, to sell, to offer for sale, or to import a patented product, or to perform a patented method.
Patent rights may be divided and licensed out in various ways, on an exclusive or non-exclusive basis. The license may be subject to limitations as to time or territory. A license may encompass an entire technology or it may involve a mere component or improvement on a technology.
United States
In the United States, "reasonable" royalties may be imposed, both after-the-fact and prospectively, by a court as a remedy for patent infringement. In patent infringement lawsuits, where the court determines an injunction to be inappropriate in light of the case's circumstances, the court may award "ongoing" royalties, or royalties based on the infringer's prospective use of the patented technology, as an alternative remedy. In the old days, US courts often used so-called "entire market rule" or "25% of the profits" rule. However, this practice was rejected by a federal appeals court in 1971. Instead, the courts are required now to use a holistic approach according to decision. The decision established 15 , to be considered, when determining reasonable royalty as a civil remedy (monetary compensation) for patent infringement, in the following order of importance:
- The royalties received by the patentee for the licensing of the patent in suit, proving or tending to prove an established royalty.
- The rates paid by the licensee for the use of other patents comparable to the patent in suit.
- The nature and scope of the license, as exclusive or non-exclusive; or as restricted or non-restricted in terms of territory or with respect to whom the manufactured product may be sold.
- The licensor’s established policy and marketing program to maintain his patent monopoly by not licensing others to use the invention or by granting licenses under special conditions designed to preserve that monopoly.
- The commercial relationship between the licensor and licensee, such as, whether they are competitors in the same territory in the same line of business; or whether they are inventor and promoter.
- The effect of selling the patented specialty in promoting sales of other products of the licensee; the existing value of the invention to the licensor as a generator of sales of his non-patented items; and the extent of such derivative or convoyed sales.
- The duration of the patent and the term of the license.
- The established profitability of the product made under the patent; its commercial success; and its current popularity.
- The utility and advantages of the patent property over the old modes or devices, if any, that had been used for working out similar results.
- The nature of the patented invention, the character of the commercial embodiment of it as owned and produced by the licensor; and the benefits to those who have used the invention.
- The extent to which the infringer has made use of the invention; and any evidence probative of the value of that use.
- The portion of the profit or of the selling price that may be customary in the particular business or in comparable businesses to allow for the use of the invention or analogous inventions.
- The portion of the realizable profit that should be credited to the invention as distinguished from non-patented elements, the manufacturing process, business risks, or significant features or improvements added by the infringer.
- The opinion testimony of qualified experts.
- The amount that a licensor (such as the patentee) and a licensee (such as the infringer) would have agreed upon (at the time the infringement began) if both had been reasonably and voluntarily trying to reach an agreement; that is, the amount which a prudent licensee—who desired, as a business proposition, to obtain a license to manufacture and sell a particular article embodying the patented invention—would have been willing to pay as a royalty and yet be able to make a reasonable profit and which amount would have been acceptable by a prudent patentee who was willing to grant a license.
At least one study analyzing a sample of 35 cases in which a court awarded an ongoing royalty has found that ongoing royalty awards "exceed by a statistically significant amount the jury-determined reasonable royalty damages".
In 2007, patent rates within the United States were:
- a pending patent on a strong business plan, royalties of the order of 1%
- issued patent, 1%+ to 2%
- the pharmaceutical with pre-clinical testing, 2–3%
In 2002, the Licensing Economics Review found in a review of 458 licence agreements over a 16-year period an average royalty rate of 7% with a range from 0% to 50%. All of these agreements may not have been at "arms length". In license negotiation, firms might derive royalties for the use of a patented technology from the retail price of the downstream licensed product.
Muslim Countries
In Muslim (Arab) countries, a royalty as a percentage of sales may not be appropriate, because of the prohibition of usury (see riba), and a flat fee may be preferred instead.
Trade mark
Trade marks are words, logos, slogans, sounds, or other distinctive expressions that distinguish the source, origin, or sponsorship of a good or service (in which they are generally known as service marks). Trade marks offer the public a means of identifying and assuring themselves of the quality of the good or service. They may bring consumers a sense of security, integrity, belonging, and a variety of intangible appeals. The value that inures to a trade mark in terms of public recognition and acceptance is known as goodwill.
A trade mark right is an exclusive right to sell or market under that mark within a geographic territory. The rights may be licensed to allow a company other than the owner to sell goods or services under the mark. A company may seek to license a trade mark it did not create to achieve instant name recognition rather than accepting the cost and risk of entering the market under its own brand that the public does not necessarily know or accept. Licensing a trade mark allows the company to take advantage of already-established goodwill and brand identification.
Like patent royalties, trade mark royalties may be assessed and divided in a variety of different ways, and are expressed as a percentage of sales volume or income, or a fixed fee per unit sold. When negotiating rates, one way companies value a trade mark is to assess the additional profit they will make from increased sales and higher prices (sometimes known as the "relief from royalty") method.
Trade mark rights and royalties are often tied up in a variety of other arrangements. Trade marks are often applied to an entire brand of products and not just a single one. Because trade mark law has as a public interest goal of the protection of a consumer, in terms of getting what they are paying for, trade mark licences are only effective if the company owning the trade mark also obtains some assurance in return that the goods will meet its quality standards. When the rights of trade mark are licensed along with a know-how, supplies, pooled advertising, etc., the result is often a franchise relationship. Franchise relationships may not specifically assign royalty payments to the trade mark licence, but may involve monthly fees and percentages of sales, among other payments.
In a long-running dispute in the United States involving the valuation of the DHL trade mark of DHL Corporation, it was reported that experts employed by the IRS surveyed a wide range of businesses and found a broad range of royalties for trade mark use from a low of 0.1% to a high of 15%.
Franchises
While a payment to employ a trade mark licence is a royalty, it is accompanied by a "guided usage manual", the use of which may be audited from time to time. However, this becomes a supervisory task when the mark is used in a franchise agreement for the sale of goods or services carrying the reputation of the mark. For a franchise, it is said, a fee is paid, even though it comprises a royalty element.
To be a franchise, the agreement must be a composite of the items:
- the right to use a trade mark to offer, sell or distribute goods or services (the trademark element)
- payment of a required royalty or fee (the fee element)
- significant assistance or control with respect to the franchisee's business (the supervisory element)
One of the above three items must not apply for the franchise agreement to be considered a trade mark agreement (and its laws and conventions). In a franchise, for which there is no convention, laws apply concerning training, brand support, operating systems/support and technical support in a written format ("Disclosure")
Copyright
Copyright law gives the owner the right to prevent others from copying, creating derivative works, or using their works. Copyrights, like patent rights, can be divided in many different ways, by the right implicated, by specific geographic or market territories, or by more specific criteria. Each may be the subject of a separate license and royalty arrangements.
Copyright royalties are often very specific to the nature of work and field of endeavor. With respect to music, royalties for performance rights in the United States are set by the Library of Congress' Copyright Royalty Board. Performance rights to recordings of a performance are usually managed by one of several performance rights organizations. Payments from these organizations to performing artists are known as residuals and performance royalties. Royalty-free music provides more direct compensation to the artists. In 1999, recording artists formed the Recording Artists' Coalition to repeal supposedly "technical revisions" to American copyright statutes which would have classified all "sound recordings" as "works for hire", effectively assigning artists' copyrights to record labels.
Book authors may sell their copyright to the publisher. Alternatively, they might receive as a royalty a certain amount per book sold. It is common in the UK for example, for authors to receive a 10% royalty on book sales.
Some photographers and musicians may choose to publish their works for a one-time payment. This is known as a royalty-free license.
Book publishing
All book-publishing royalties are paid by the publisher, who determines an author's royalty rate, except in rare cases in which the author can demand high advances and royalties.
For most cases, the publishers advance an amount (part of the royalty) which can constitute the bulk of the author's total income plus whatever little flows from the "running royalty" stream. Some costs may be attributed to the advance paid, which depletes further advances to be paid or from the running royalty paid. The author and the publisher can independently draw up the agreement that binds them or alongside an agent representing the author. There are many risks for the author—definition of cover price, the retail price, "net price", the discounts on the sale, the bulk sales on the POD (publish on demand) platform, the term of the agreement, audit of the publishers accounts in case of impropriety, etc. which an agent can provide.
The following illustrates the income to an author on the basis chosen for royalty, particularly in POD, which minimizes losses from inventory and is based on computer technologies.
Book-publishing Royalties – "Net" and "Retail" Compared Retail Basis Net Basis Cover Price, $ 15.00 15.00 Discount to Booksellers 50% 50% Wholesale Price, $ 7.50 7.50 Printing Cost, $ (200 pp Book)
3.50 3.50 Net Income, $ 4.00 4.00 Royalty Rate 20% 20% Royalty Calcn. 0.20x15 0.20x4 Royalty, $ 3.00 0.80
Hardback royalties on the published price of trade books usually range from 10% to 12.5%, with 15% for more important authors. On paperback it is usually 7.5% to 10%, going up to 12.5% only in exceptional cases. All the royalties displayed below are on the "cover price". Paying 15% to the author can mean that the other 85% of the cost pays for editing and proof-reading, printing and binding, overheads, and the profits (if any) to the publisher.
The publishing company pays no royalty on bulk purchases of books since the buying price may be a third of the cover price sold on a singles basis.
Unlike the UK, the United States does not specify a "maximum retail price" for books that serves as base for calculation.
Based on net receipts
Methods of calculating royalties changed during the 1980s, due to the rise of retail chain booksellers, which demanded increasing discounts from publishers. As a result, rather than paying royalties based on a percentage of a book's cover price, publishers preferred to pay royalties based on their net receipts. According to The Writers' and Artists' Yearbook of 1984, under the new arrangement, "appropriate [upward] adjustments are of course made to the royalty figure and the arrangement is of no disadvantage to the author."
Despite this assurance, in 1991, Frederick Nolan, author and former publishing executive, explained that "net receipts" royalties are often more in the interest of publishers than authors:
It makes sense for the publisher to pay the author on the basis of what he receives, but it by no means makes it a good deal for the author. Example: 10,000 copies of a $20 book with a 10 percent cover-price royalty will earn him $20,000. The same number sold but discounted at 55 percent will net the publisher $90,000; the author's ten percent of that figure yields him $9,000. Which is one reason why publishers prefer "net receipts" contracts....Among the many other advantages (to the publisher) of such contracts is the fact that they make possible what is called a 'sheet deal'. In this, the (multinational) publisher of that same 10,000 copy print run, can substantially reduce his printing cost by 'running on' a further 10,000 copies (that is to say, printing but not binding them), and then further profit by selling these 'sheets' at cost-price or even lower if he so chooses to subsidiaries or overseas branches, then paying the author 10 percent of 'net receipts' from that deal. The overseas subsidiaries bind up the sheets into book form and sell at full price for a nice profit to the Group as a whole. The only one who loses is the author.
In 2003, two American authors Ken Englade and Patricia Simpson sued HarperCollins (USA) successfully for selling their work to its foreign affiliates at improperly high discounts ("Harper Collins is essentially selling books to itself, at discounted rates, upon which it then calculates the author's royalty, and then Harper Collins shares in the extra profit when the book is resold to the consumer by the foreign affiliates, without paying the author any further royalty.")
This forced a "class action" readjustment for thousands of authors contracted by HarperCollins between November 1993 and June 1999.
Music
Unlike other forms of intellectual property, music royalties have a strong linkage to individuals – composers (score), songwriters (lyrics) and writers of musical plays – in that they can own the exclusive copyright to created music and can license it for performance independent of corporates. Recording companies and the performing artists that create a "sound recording" of the music enjoy a separate set of copyrights and royalties from the sale of recordings and from their digital transmission (depending on national laws).
With the advent of pop music and major innovations in technology in the communication and presentations of media, the subject of music royalties has become complex.
Art royalties
Resale royalty or droit de suite
Art Resale Royalty is a right to a royalty payment upon resales of art works, that applies in some jurisdictions. Whilst there are currently approximately 60 countries that have some sort of Resale Royalty on their statute books, evidence of resale schemes that can be said to be actually operating schemes is restricted to Europe, Australia and the American state of California. For example, in May 2011 the European commissions ec.europa webpage on Resale royalty stated that, under the heading 'Indicative list of third countries (Article 7.2)' : 'A letter was sent to Member States on 1 March 2006 requesting that they provide a list of third countries which meet these requirements and that they also provide evidence of application. To date the commission has not been supplied with evidence for any third country which demonstrates that they qualify for inclusion on this list.' [The emphasis is from the European commission web page.]
Apart from placing a levy on the resale of some art-like objects, there are few common facets to the various national schemes. Most schemes prescribe a minimum amount that the artwork must receive before the artist can invoke resale rights (usually the hammer price or price). Some countries prescribe and others such as Australia, do not prescribe, the maximum royalty that can be received. Most do prescribe the calculation basis of the royalty. Some country's make the usage of the royalty compulsory. Some country's prescribe a sole monopoly collection service agency, while others like the UK and France, allow multiple agencies. Some schemes involve varying degrees of retrospective application and other schemes such as Australia's are not retrospective at all. In some cases, for example Germany, an openly tax-like use is made of the "royalties"; Half of the money collected is redistributed to fund public programs.
The New Zealand and Canadian governments have not proceeded with any sort of artist resale scheme. The Australian scheme does not apply to the first resale of artworks purchased prior to the schemes enactment( June 2010) and individual usage of the right (by Australian artists) is not compulsory. In Australia artists have a case by case right (under clause 22/23 of the Act) to refuse consent to the usage of the right by the appointed collection society and/or make their own collection arrangements. Details of the Australian scheme can be gotten from the website of the sole appointed Australian agency; The "Copyright Agency Limited".
The UK scheme is in the context of common-law countries an oddity; No other common-law country has mandated an individual economic right where actual usage of the right is compulsory for the individual right holder. Whether the common law conception of an individual economic right as an "individual right of control of usage" is compatible with the Code Civil origins of droit de suite is open to question.
The UK is the largest art resale market where a form of ARR is operating, details of how the royalty is calculated as a portion of sale price in the UK can be accessed here DACS In the UK, the scheme was, in early 2012, extended to all artists still in copyright. In most European jurisdictions the right has the same duration as the term of copyright. In California law, heirs receive royalty for 20 years.
The royalty applies to any work of graphic or plastic art such as a ceramic, collage, drawing, engraving, glassware, lithograph, painting, photograph, picture, print, sculpture, tapestry. However, a copy of a work is not to be regarded as a work unless the copy is one of a limited number made by the artist or under the artist's authority. In the UK the resale of a work bought directly from the artist and then resold within 3 years for a value of €10,000 or less is not affected by the royalty.
The situation as to how ARR applies in situations where an art work is physically made by a person or persons who are not the 'name artist' who first exhibits and sells the work is not clear. In particular whilst ARR is inalienable it seems conceivable that in cases where the copyright on an artwork is transferred/sold, prior to the first sale of an artwork, the inalienable ARR right is also effectively sold transferred.
Whether resale royalties are of net economic benefit to artists is a highly contested area. Many economic studies have seriously questioned the assumptions underlying the argument that resale royalties have net benefits to artists. Many modelings have suggested that resale royalties could be actually harmful to living artists' economic positions. Australia's chief advocate for the adoption of artist resale royalties the collection society, Viscopy, commissioned in 2004 a report from Access Economics to model the likely impact of their scheme. In the resulting report, Access Economics warned that the claim of net benefit to artists was: "based upon extremely unrealistic assumptions, in particular the assumption that seller and buyer behaviour would be completely unaffected by the introduction of RRR [ARR]" and that, "Access Economics considers that the results of this analysis are both unhelpful and potentially misleading."
Software royalties
There is simply too much computer software to consider the royalties applicable to each. The following is a guide to royalty rates:
- Computer Software: 10.5% (average), 6.8% (median)
- Internet: 11.7% (average), 7.5% (median)
For the development of customer-specific software one will have to consider:
- Total software development cost
- Break-even cost (if the software can be sold to many agencies)
- Ownership of code (if the client's, he bears the development cost)
- Life of the software (usually short or requiring maintenance)
- Risk in development (high, commanding A high price)
Other royalty arrangements
The term "royalty" also covers areas outside of IP and technology licensing, such as oil, gas, and mineral royalties paid to the owner of a property by a resources development company in exchange for the right to exploit the resource. In a business project the promoter, financier, LHS enabled the transaction but are no longer actively interested may have a royalty right to a portion of the income, or profits, of the business. This sort of royalty is often expressed as a contract right to receive money based on a royalty formula, rather than an actual ownership interest in the business. In some businesses this sort of royalty is sometimes called an override.
Alliances and partnerships
Royalties may exist in technological alliances and partnerships. The latter is more than mere access to secret technical or a trade right to accomplish an objective. It is, in the last decade of the past century, and the first of this one of the major means of technology transfer. Its importance for the licensor and the licensee lies in its access to markets and raw materials, and labor, when the international trend is towards globalization.
There are three main groups when it comes to technological alliances. They are Joint-ventures (sometimes abbreviated JV), the Franchises and Strategic Alliances (SA).
- Joint-ventures are usually between companies long in contact with a purpose. JVs are very formal forms of association, and depending on the country where they are situated, subject to a rigid code of rules, in which the public may or may not have an opportunity to participate in capital; partly depending on the size of capital required, and partly on Governmental regulations. They usually revolve around products and normally involve an inventive step.
- Franchises revolve around services and they are closely connected with trademarks, an example of which is McDonald's. Although franchises have no convention like trademarks or copyrights they can be mistaken as a trademark-copyright in agreements. The franchisor has close control over the franchisee, which, in legal terms cannot be tie-ins such as frachisee located in an areas owned by the franchisor.
- Strategic Alliances can involve a project (such as bridge building). a product or a service. As the name implies, is more a matter of 'marriage of convenience' when two parties want to associate to take up a particular (but modest) short-term task but generally are uncomfortable with the other. But the strategic alliance could be a test of compatibility for the forming of a joint venture company and a precedent step.
Note that all of these ventures s could be in a third county. JVs and franchises are rarely found formed within a county. They largely involve third countries.
On occasion, a JV or SA may be wholly oriented to research and development, typically involving multiple organizations working on an agreed form of engagement. The Airbus is an example of such.
Technical assistance and service in technology transfer
Firms in developing countries often are asked by the supplier of know-how or patent licensing to consider technical service (TS) and technical assistance (TA) as elements of the technology transfer process and to pay "royalty" on them. TS and TA are associated with the IP (intellectual property) transferred – and, sometimes, dependent on its acquisition – but they are, by no means, IP. TA and TS may also be the sole part of the transfer or the transferor of the IP, their concurrent supplier. They are seldom met with in the developed countries, which sometimes view even know-how as similar to TS.
TS comprises services which are the specialized knowledge of firms or acquired by them for operating a special process. It is often a "bundle" of services which can by itself meet an objective or help in meeting it. It is delivered over time, at end of which the acquirer becomes proficient to be independent of the service. In this process, no consideration is given on whether the transfer of the proprietary element has been concluded or not.
On the other hand, technical assistance is a package of assistance given on a short timetable. It can range variously from procurement of equipment for a project, inspection services on behalf of the buyer, the training of buyer's personnel and the supply technical or managerial staff. Again, TA is independent of IP services.
The payment for these services is a fee, not a royalty. The TS fee is dependent on how many of the specialized staff of its supplier are required and over what period of time. Sometimes, the "learning" capacity to whom the TS is supplied is involved. In any case, the cost per service-hour should be calculated and evaluated. Note that in selecting a TS supplier (often the IP supplier), experience and dependency are critical.
In the case of TA there is usually a plurality of firms and choice is feasible.
Approaches to royalty rate
Intellectual property
This section does not cite any sources.(September 2008) |
The rate of royalty applied in a given case is determined by various factors, the most notable of which are:
- Market drivers and demand structure
- Territorial extent of rights
- Exclusivity of rights
- Level of innovation and stage of development (see The Technology Life Cycle)
- Sustainability of the technology
- Degree and competitive availability of other technologies
- Inherent risk
- Strategic need
- The portfolio of rights negotiated
- Fundability
- Deal-reward structure (negotiation strength)
To correctly gauge royalty rates, the following criteria must be taken into consideration:
- The transaction is at "arms-length"
- There is a willing buyer and a willing seller
- The transaction is not under compulsion
Rate determination and illustrative royalties
This section does not cite any sources.(September 2008) |
There are three general approaches to assess the applicable royalty rate in the licensing of intellectual property. They are
- The Cost Approach
- The Comparable Market Approach
- The Income Approach
For a fair evaluation of the royalty rate, the relationship of the parties to the contract should:
- – be at "arms-length" (related parties such as the subsidiary and the parent company need to transact as though they were independent parties)
- – be viewed as acting free and without compulsion
Cost approach
The Cost Approach considers the several elements of cost that may have been entered to create the intellectual property and to seek a royalty rate that will recapture the expense of its development and obtain a return that is commensurate with its expected life. Costs considered could include R&D expenditures, pilot-plant and test-marketing costs, technology upgrading expenses, patent application expenditure and the like.
The method has limited utility since the technology is not priced competitively on "what the market can bear" principles or in the context of the price of similar technologies. More importantly, by lacking optimization (through additional expense), it may earn benefits below its potential.
However, the method may be appropriate when a technology is licensed out during its R&D phase as happens with venture capital investments or it is licensed out during one of the stages of clinical trials of a pharmaceutical.
In the former case, the venture capitalist obtains an equity position in the company (developing the technology) in exchange for financing a part of the development cost (recovering it, and obtaining an appropriate margin, when the company gets acquired or it goes public through the IPO route).
Recovery of costs, with opportunity of gain, is also feasible when development can be followed stage-wise as shown below for a pharmaceutical undergoing clinical trials (the licensee pays higher royalties for the product as it moves through the normal stages of its development):
Success State of development | Royalty rates (%) | Nature |
---|---|---|
Pre-clinical success | 0–5 | in-vitro |
Phase I (safety) | 5–10 | 100 healthy people |
Phase II (efficacy) | 8–15 | 300 subjects |
Phase III (effectiveness) | 10–20 | several thousand patients |
Launched product | 20+ | regulatory body approval |
A similar approach is used when custom software is licensed (an in-license, i.e. an incoming license). The product is accepted on a royalty schedule depending on the software meeting set stage-wise specifications with acceptable error levels in performance tests.
Comparable market approach
Here the cost and the risk of development are disregarded. The royalty rate is determined from comparing competing or similar technologies in an industry, modified by considerations of useful "remaining life" of the technology in that industry and contracting elements such as exclusivity provisions, front-end royalties, field of use restrictions, geographic limitations and the "technology bundle" (the mix of patents, know-how, trade-mark rights, etc.) accompanying it. Economist J. Gregory Sidak explains that comparable licenses, when selected correctly, "reveal what the licensor and the licensee consider to be fair compensation for the use of the patented technology" and thus "will most accurately depict the price that a licensee would willingly pay for that technology." The Federal Circuit has on numerous occasions confirmed that the comparable market approach is a reliable methodology to calculate a reasonable royalty.
Although widely used, the prime difficulty with this method is obtaining access to data on comparable technologies and the terms of the agreements that incorporate them. Fortunately, there are several recognized[by whom?] organizations (see "Royalty Rate Websites" listed at the end of this article) who have comprehensive[citation needed] information on both royalty rates and the principal terms of the agreements of which they are a part. There are also IP-related organizations, such as the Licensing Executives Society, which enable its members to access and share privately assembled data.
The two tables shown below are drawn, selectively, from information that is available with an IP-related organization and on-line. The first depicts the range and distribution of royalty rates in agreements. The second shows the royalty rate ranges in select technology sectors (latter data sourced from: Dan McGavock of IPC Group, Chicago, USA).
Royalty Distribution Analysis in Industry Industry Licenses (nos.) Min. Royalty,% Max. Royalty,% Average,% Median,% Automotive 35 1.0 15.0 4.7 4.0 Computers 68 0.2 15.0 5.2 4.0 Consumer Gds 90 0.0 17.0 5.5 5.0 Electronics 132 0.5 15.0 4.3 4.0 Healthcare 280 0.1 77.0 5.8 4.8 Internet 47 0.3 40.0 11.7 7.5 Mach.Tools. 84 0.5 26 5.2 4.6 Pharma/Bio 328 0.1 40.0 7.0 5.1 Software 119 0.0 70.0 10.5 6.8
Royalty Rate Segmentation in Some Technology Sectors Industry 0–2% 2–5% 5–10% 10–15% 15–20% 20–25% Aerospace 50% 50% Chemical 16.5% 58.1% 24.3% 0.8% 0.4% Computer 62.5% 31.3% 6.3% Electronics 50.0% 25.0% 25.0% Healthcare 3.3% 51.7% 45.0% Pharmaceuticals 23.6% 32.1% 29.3% 12.5% 1.1% 0.7% Telecom 40.0% 37.3% 23.6%
Commercial sources also provide information that is invaluable for making comparisons. The following table provides typical information that is obtainable, for instance, from Royaltystat:
- Sample License Parameters
Reference: 7787 Effective Date: 1 October 1998 SIC Code: 2870 SEC Filed Date: 26 July 2005 SEC Filer: Eden Bioscience Corp Royalty Rate: 2.000 (%) SEC Filing: 10-Q Royalty Base: Net Sales Agreement Type: Patent Exclusive: Yes Licensor: Cornell Research Foundation, Inc. Licensee: Eden Bioscience Corp. Lump-Sum Pay: Research support is $150,000 for 1 year. Duration: 17-year(s) Territory: Worldwide
Coverage : Exclusive patent license to make, have made, use and sell products incorporating biological materials, including genes, proteins and peptide fragments, expression systems, cells, and antibodies, for the field of plant disease
The comparability between transactions requires a comparison of the significant economic conditions that may affect the contracting parties:
- Similarity of geographies
- Relevant date
- Same industry
- Market size and its economic development;
- Contracting or expanding markets
- Market activity: whether wholesale, retail, other
- Relative market shares of contracting entities
- Location-specific costs of production and distribution
- Competitive environment in each geography
- Fair alternatives to contracting parties
Income approach
The Income approach focuses on the licensor estimating the profits generated by the licensee and obtaining an appropriate share of the generated profit. It is unrelated to costs of technology development or the costs of competing technologies.
The approach requires the licensee (or licensor): (a) to generate a cash-flow projection of incomes and expenses over the life-span of the license under an agreed scenario of incomes and costs (b) determining the Net Present Value, NPV of the profit stream, based on a selected discount factor, and c) negotiating the division of such profit between the licensor and the licensee.
The NPV of a future income is always lower than its current value because an income in the future is attended by risk. In other words, an income in the future needs to be discounted, in some manner, to obtain its present equivalent. The factor by which a future income is reduced is known as the 'discount rate'. Thus, $1.00 received a year from now is worth $0.9091 at a 10% discount rate, and its discounted value will be still lower two years down the line.
The actual discount factor used depends on the risk assumed by the principal gainer in the transaction. For instance, a mature technology worked in different geographies, will carry a lower risk of non-performance (thus, a lower discount rate) than a technology being applied for the first time. A similar situation arises when there is the option of working the technology in one of two different regions; the risk elements in each region would be different.
The method is treated in greater detail, using illustrative data, in Royalty Assessment.
The licensor's share of the income is usually set by the "25% rule of thumb", which is said to be even used by tax authorities in the US and Europe for arms-length transactions. The share is on the operating profit of the licensee firm. Even where such division is held contentious, the rule can still be the starting point of negotiations.
Following are three aspects that are important for the profit:
- (a) the profit that accrues to the licensee may not arise solely through the engine of the technology. There are returns from the mix of assets it employs such as fixed and working capital and the returns from intangible assets such as distribution systems, trained workforce, etc. Allowances need to be made for them.
- (b) profits are also generated by thrusts in the general economy, gains from infrastructure, and the basket of licensed rights – patents, trademark, know-how. A lower royalty rate may apply in an advanced country where large market volumes can be commanded, or where protection to the technology is more secure than in an emerging economy (or perhaps, for other reasons, the inverse).
- (c) the royalty rate is only one aspect of the negotiation. Contractual provisions such as an exclusive license, rights to sub-license, warranties on the performance of technology etc may enhance the advantages to the licensee, which is not compensated by the 25% metric.
The basic advantage of this approach, which is perhaps the most widely applied, is that the royalty rate can be negotiated without comparative data on how other agreements have been transacted. In fact, it is almost ideal for a case where precedent does not exist.
It is, perhaps, relevant to note that the IRS also uses these three methods, in modified form, to assess the attributable income, or division of income, from a royalty-based transaction between a US company and its foreign subsidiary (since US law requires that a foreign subsidiary pay an appropriate royalty to the parent company).
Other compensation modes
Royalties are only one among many ways of compensating owners for use of an asset. Others include:
- buying the asset outright, possibly with a leaseback arrangement
- offering the licensor an equity position in the licensee company
- staged milestone payments (as in drug development and commissioned software arrangements)
- lump sum payment made to the licensor in one or more installments
- cross-licensing agreements with or without cash payments, and
- entering into a strategic alliance or Joint Venture.
In discussing the licensing of Intellectual Property, the terms valuation and evaluation need to be understood in their rigorous terms. Evaluation is the process of assessing a license in terms of the specific metrics of a particular negotiation, which may include its circumstances, the geographical spread of licensed rights, product range, market width, licensee competitiveness, growth prospects, etc.
On the other hand, valuation is the fair market value (FMV) of the asset – trademark, patent or know-how – at which it can be sold between a willing buyer and willing seller in the context of best awareness of circumstances. The FMV of the IP, where assessable, may itself be a metric for evaluation.
If an emerging company is listed on the stock market, the market value of its intellectual property can be estimated from the data of the balance sheet using the equivalence:
Market Capitalization = Net Working capital + Net Fixed assets + Routine Intangible assets + IP
where the IP is the residual after deducting the other components from the market valuation of the stock. One of the most significant intangibles may be the work-force.
The method may be quite useful for valuing trademarks of a listed company if it is mainly or the only IP in play (franchising companies).
See also
- Celebrity bond
- Copyright transfer agreement
- Payola
- Revenue based financing
- Royalty-free
- AuthorShare a system for charging royalties for the second hand sale of books and other media.
References
- "Focus: Tax and Intellectual Property – April 2004". Allens Arthur Robinson. Archived from the original on 3 September 2007. Retrieved 13 September 2007.
- "Royalty (definition)". law.com. Archived from the original on 9 March 2012. Retrieved 13 September 2007.
- United Nations Industrial Development Organization (1996). Manual on Technology Transfer Negotiation. Vienna: United Nations Industrial Development Organization. ISBN 92-1-106302-7.
- Guidelines for Evaluation of Transfer of Technology Agreements, United Nations, New York, 1979
- Licensing Guide for Developing Countries: A Guide on the Legal Aspects of the Negotiation and Preparation of Industrial Property Licenses and Technology Transfer Agreements Appropriate to the Needs of Developing Countries. Geneva: World Intellectual Property Organization. 1977. ISBN 92-805-0395-2.
- UNIDO International Workshop on Technology Transfer Negotiation and Plant Level Technology Needs Assessment, 7–8 December 1999, New Delhi.
- Dave Tyrrell. "Intellectual Property & Licensing". Vertex. Archived from the original on 23 March 2019. Retrieved 14 September 2007.
- "Royalty interest (definition)". Schlumberger. Archived from the original on 29 June 2006. Retrieved 13 September 2007.
- Calculating Royalty. Indigenous and Northern Affairs Canada. 2010. Retrieved 12 July 2018. "Archived copy". Archived from the original on 17 July 2018. Retrieved 10 September 2021.
{{cite web}}
: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link) CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link) - "oilgas1031.com". oilgas1031.com. Archived from the original on 6 April 2013. Retrieved 4 May 2013.
- "Sell Gas Royalty, Sell Oil Royalty, Sell Mineral Rights & Royalties". broadmoorminerals.com. Archived from the original on 27 November 2013. Retrieved 27 November 2013.
- "Types of Wind Royalties". Blue Mesa Minerals. Retrieved 7 August 2023.
- "J. Gregory Sidak, Ongoing Royalties for Patent Infringement, 24 TEX. INTELL. PROP. L.J. at 6 (forthcoming 2016)". Archived from the original on 24 August 2017. Retrieved 4 February 2016.
- https://scholarlycommons.law.wlu.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=4304&context=wlulr [bare URL]
- Lance Wyatt, Keeping Up with the Game: The Use of the Nash Bargaining Solution in Patent Infringement Cases, 31 Santa Clara High Tech. L.J. 427 (2015). Available at: http://digitalcommons.law.scu.edu/chtlj/vol31/iss3/2
- Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp. (318 F. Supp. 1116, 1116 (S.D.N.Y. 1970), modified sub nom. Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Champion Papers, Inc., 446 F.2d 295, 2d Cir. 1971)
- "Georgia-pacific Corporation, Appellant, v. U. S. Plywood-champion Papers Inc., Appellee, 446 F.2d 295 (2d Cir. 1971)". Justia Law. This article incorporates text from this source, which is in the public domain.
- "Patent Infringement Damages Expert Witness Georgia Pacific Factors". No World Borders - Experts in healthcare.
- "J. Gregory Sidak, Ongoing Royalties for Patent Infringement, 24 TEX. INTELL. PROP. L.J. at 14 (forthcoming 2016)". Archived from the original on 24 August 2017. Retrieved 4 February 2016.
- "Ranges of royalty rates, and royalty guidelines, U.S. Pharmaceutical Industry". Archived from the original on 28 September 2007. Retrieved 19 July 2007.
- Licensing Economics Review. The Royalty Rate Journal of Intellectual Property, December 2002, p. 8.
- "Sample: License Parameters". Archived from the original on 13 April 2008. Retrieved 26 October 2007.
- J. Gregory Sidak (2014). "The Proper Royalty Base for Patent Damages (10 J. COMPETITION L. & ECON 989, 990)". criterioneconomics.com. Archived from the original on 30 October 2015. Retrieved 20 October 2015.
- Mallat, Chibli. "Joint ventures in Lebanese and European law". mallat.com. Archived from the original on 14 June 2011. Retrieved 29 November 2010.
- "DHL Corporation and Subsidiaries vs. Commissioner of Internal Revenue, Docket Nos. 19570-95, 26103-95, United States Tax Court" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 7 March 2008. Retrieved 9 September 2007.
- "Four little words". 28 August 2000. Archived from the original on 13 January 2010. Retrieved 15 March 2007.
- "Don Henley Speaks on Behalf of Recording Artists". Archived from the original on 17 January 2006. Retrieved 15 March 2007.
- The Writers and Artists Yearbook, 1984, p.422
- "Malcolm v. Oxford: Fred Nolan". www.akmedea.com. Archived from the original on 5 January 2016. Retrieved 5 January 2016.
- "Casetext". casetext.com. Archived from the original on 5 January 2016. Retrieved 5 January 2016.
- "Englade & Simpson vs. HarperCollins". www.akmedea.com. Archived from the original on 4 March 2016. Retrieved 5 January 2016.
- "» Internal Market » Copyright » Resale Right". European Commission: The EU Single Market. Archived from the original on 27 January 2012. Retrieved 12 December 2011.
- "About the artists resale royalty scheme". resaleroyalty.org.au. Archived from the original on 25 February 2011. Retrieved 29 November 2010.
- Kirstein, R./Schmidtchen, D. (2001); Do Artists Benefit from Resale Royalties? An Economic Analysis of a New EU Directive. In: Deffains, B./Kirat, T. (eds.): Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries; The Economics of Legal Relationships Vol. 6, Elsevier Science, Amsterdam et al., 231–248.
- "Viscopy Access Economics" (PDF). Retrieved 29 November 2010.[dead link ]
- "Royalty Rates – Software Development Profit Sharing/Royalty Rates Options". Northwest Data Solutions. Archived from the original on 28 November 2018. Retrieved 28 November 2018.
- Manual on Technology Transfer Negotiation (A reference for policy-makers and practitioners on Technology Transfer),1996 United Nations Industrial Development Organization, Vienna, 1990, ISBN 92-1-106302-7
- Patterns of Internationalization for Developing Country Enterprises, United Nations Industrial Organization, Vienna, Austria 2008, ISBN 978-92-1-106443-8
- Manual on Technology Transfer Negotiation (A reference for policy-makers and practitioners on Technology Transfer),1996 United Nations Industrial Development Organization, Vienna, 1990, ISBN 92-1-106302-7, pp 260–261
- "J. Gregory Sidak, Apportionment, FRAND Royalties, and Comparable Licenses After Ericsson v. D-Link, 2016 U. Ill. L. REV. (forthcoming)". Archived from the original on 17 March 2016. Retrieved 5 February 2016.
- Ericsson, Inc. v. D-Link Systems, Inc., 773 F.3d 1201 (Fed. Cir. 2014); LaserDynamics, Inc. v. Quanta Comput., Inc., 694 F.3d 51 (Fed. Cir. 2012).
- ; Jarosz, John; Mulhern, Carla (December 2002). "Use Of The 25 Per Cent Rule In Valuing IP". Archived from the original on 12 September 2009. Retrieved 20 September 2007.
- David G. Weiler. "Valuing Your Intellectual Property for Strategic Alliances and Financing". Archived from the original on 13 November 2006. Retrieved 20 September 2007.
- "Sample: License Parameters". Archived from the original on 8 December 2006. Retrieved 26 September 2007.
- "Treasury Evaluations". Archived from the original on 20 September 2007. Retrieved 27 September 2007.
External links
- Quotations related to Royalty payment at Wikiquote
- "Royalty Rate Websites"
- "CPT page on Royalties on patents for health care inventions"
This article includes a list of general references but it lacks sufficient corresponding inline citations Please help to improve this article by introducing more precise citations October 2024 Learn how and when to remove this message A royalty payment is a payment made by one party to another that owns a particular asset for the right to ongoing use of that asset Royalties are typically agreed upon as a percentage of gross or net revenues derived from the use of an asset or a fixed price per unit sold of an item of such but there are also other modes and metrics of compensation A royalty interest is the right to collect a stream of future royalty payments A license agreement defines the terms under which a resource or property are licensed by one party to another either without restriction or subject to a limitation on term business or geographic territory type of product etc License agreements can be regulated particularly where a government is the resource owner or they can be private contracts that follow a general structure However certain types of franchise agreements have comparable provisions clarification needed Non renewable resourcesA landowner with petroleum or mineral rights to their property may license those rights to another party In exchange for allowing the other party to extract the resources the landowner receives either a resource rent or a royalty payment based on the value of the resources sold When a government owns the resource the transaction often has to follow legal and regulatory requirements citation needed In the United States fee simple ownership of mineral rights is possible and payments of royalties to private citizens occurs quite often Local taxing authorities may impose a severance tax on the unrenewable natural resources extracted or severed from within their authority The Federal Government receives royalties on production on federal lands managed by the Bureau of Ocean Energy Management Regulation and Enforcement formerly the Minerals Management Service citation needed An example from Canada s northern territories is the federal Frontier Lands Petroleum Royalty Regulations The royalty rate starts at 1 of gross revenues of the first 18 months of commercial production and increases by 1 every 18 months to a maximum of 5 until initial costs have been recovered at which point the royalty rate is set at 5 of gross revenues or 30 of net revenues In this manner risks and profits are shared between the government of Canada as resource owner and the petroleum developer This attractive royalty rate is intended to encourage oil and gas exploration in the remote Canadian frontier lands where costs and risks are higher than other locations In many jurisdictions in North America oil and gas royalty interests are considered real property under the NAICS classification code and qualify for a 1031 like kind exchange Oil and gas royalties are paid as a set percentage on all revenue less any deductions that may be taken by the well operator as specifically noted in the lease agreement The revenue decimal or royalty interest that a mineral owner receives is calculated as a function of the percentage of the total drilling unit to which a specific owner holds the mineral interest the royalty rate defined in that owner s mineral lease and any tract participation factors applied to the specific tracts owned As a standard example for every 100 bbl of oil sold on a U S federal well with a 25 royalty the U S government receives 25 The U S government does not pay and will only collect revenues All risk and liability lie upon the operator of the well Royalties in the lumber industry are called stumpage Wind RoyaltiesLandowners who host wind turbines are often paid wind royalties and those nearby may be paid nuisance payments to compensate for noise and flicker effects Wind royalties are usually paid quarterly semi annually or annually and the royalty can be a flat rate or variable payment based on production or a combination of both Unlike oil and gas royalties which typically decline over time wind royalties often have an escalation clause making them more valuable over time Because there is not yet a robust body of law regarding wind royalties the legal implications of severing wind rights are still unknown Several states including Colorado Kansas Oklahoma North Dakota South Dakota Nebraska Montana and Wyoming have enacted anti severance statutes preventing the wind estate from being severed from the surface Regardless the ownership of wind royalties and compensation payments can be transferred from the landowner to another party Over time wind royalties will be fractioned similarly to oil and gas royalties PatentsAn intangible asset such as a patent right gives the owner an exclusive right to prevent others from practicing the patented technology in the country issuing the patent for the term of the patent The right may be enforced in a lawsuit for monetary damages and or imprisonment for violation on the patent In accordance with a patent license royalties are paid to the patent owner in exchange for the right to practice one or more of the basic patent rights to manufacture to use to sell to offer for sale or to import a patented product or to perform a patented method Patent rights may be divided and licensed out in various ways on an exclusive or non exclusive basis The license may be subject to limitations as to time or territory A license may encompass an entire technology or it may involve a mere component or improvement on a technology United States In the United States reasonable royalties may be imposed both after the fact and prospectively by a court as a remedy for patent infringement In patent infringement lawsuits where the court determines an injunction to be inappropriate in light of the case s circumstances the court may award ongoing royalties or royalties based on the infringer s prospective use of the patented technology as an alternative remedy In the old days US courts often used so called entire market rule or 25 of the profits rule However this practice was rejected by a federal appeals court in 1971 Instead the courts are required now to use a holistic approach according to decision The decision established 15 to be considered when determining reasonable royalty as a civil remedy monetary compensation for patent infringement in the following order of importance The royalties received by the patentee for the licensing of the patent in suit proving or tending to prove an established royalty The rates paid by the licensee for the use of other patents comparable to the patent in suit The nature and scope of the license as exclusive or non exclusive or as restricted or non restricted in terms of territory or with respect to whom the manufactured product may be sold The licensor s established policy and marketing program to maintain his patent monopoly by not licensing others to use the invention or by granting licenses under special conditions designed to preserve that monopoly The commercial relationship between the licensor and licensee such as whether they are competitors in the same territory in the same line of business or whether they are inventor and promoter The effect of selling the patented specialty in promoting sales of other products of the licensee the existing value of the invention to the licensor as a generator of sales of his non patented items and the extent of such derivative or convoyed sales The duration of the patent and the term of the license The established profitability of the product made under the patent its commercial success and its current popularity The utility and advantages of the patent property over the old modes or devices if any that had been used for working out similar results The nature of the patented invention the character of the commercial embodiment of it as owned and produced by the licensor and the benefits to those who have used the invention The extent to which the infringer has made use of the invention and any evidence probative of the value of that use The portion of the profit or of the selling price that may be customary in the particular business or in comparable businesses to allow for the use of the invention or analogous inventions The portion of the realizable profit that should be credited to the invention as distinguished from non patented elements the manufacturing process business risks or significant features or improvements added by the infringer The opinion testimony of qualified experts The amount that a licensor such as the patentee and a licensee such as the infringer would have agreed upon at the time the infringement began if both had been reasonably and voluntarily trying to reach an agreement that is the amount which a prudent licensee who desired as a business proposition to obtain a license to manufacture and sell a particular article embodying the patented invention would have been willing to pay as a royalty and yet be able to make a reasonable profit and which amount would have been acceptable by a prudent patentee who was willing to grant a license At least one study analyzing a sample of 35 cases in which a court awarded an ongoing royalty has found that ongoing royalty awards exceed by a statistically significant amount the jury determined reasonable royalty damages In 2007 patent rates within the United States were a pending patent on a strong business plan royalties of the order of 1 issued patent 1 to 2 the pharmaceutical with pre clinical testing 2 3 In 2002 the Licensing Economics Review found in a review of 458 licence agreements over a 16 year period an average royalty rate of 7 with a range from 0 to 50 All of these agreements may not have been at arms length In license negotiation firms might derive royalties for the use of a patented technology from the retail price of the downstream licensed product Muslim Countries In Muslim Arab countries a royalty as a percentage of sales may not be appropriate because of the prohibition of usury see riba and a flat fee may be preferred instead Trade markTrade marks are words logos slogans sounds or other distinctive expressions that distinguish the source origin or sponsorship of a good or service in which they are generally known as service marks Trade marks offer the public a means of identifying and assuring themselves of the quality of the good or service They may bring consumers a sense of security integrity belonging and a variety of intangible appeals The value that inures to a trade mark in terms of public recognition and acceptance is known as goodwill A trade mark right is an exclusive right to sell or market under that mark within a geographic territory The rights may be licensed to allow a company other than the owner to sell goods or services under the mark A company may seek to license a trade mark it did not create to achieve instant name recognition rather than accepting the cost and risk of entering the market under its own brand that the public does not necessarily know or accept Licensing a trade mark allows the company to take advantage of already established goodwill and brand identification Like patent royalties trade mark royalties may be assessed and divided in a variety of different ways and are expressed as a percentage of sales volume or income or a fixed fee per unit sold When negotiating rates one way companies value a trade mark is to assess the additional profit they will make from increased sales and higher prices sometimes known as the relief from royalty method Trade mark rights and royalties are often tied up in a variety of other arrangements Trade marks are often applied to an entire brand of products and not just a single one Because trade mark law has as a public interest goal of the protection of a consumer in terms of getting what they are paying for trade mark licences are only effective if the company owning the trade mark also obtains some assurance in return that the goods will meet its quality standards When the rights of trade mark are licensed along with a know how supplies pooled advertising etc the result is often a franchise relationship Franchise relationships may not specifically assign royalty payments to the trade mark licence but may involve monthly fees and percentages of sales among other payments In a long running dispute in the United States involving the valuation of the DHL trade mark of DHL Corporation it was reported that experts employed by the IRS surveyed a wide range of businesses and found a broad range of royalties for trade mark use from a low of 0 1 to a high of 15 Franchises While a payment to employ a trade mark licence is a royalty it is accompanied by a guided usage manual the use of which may be audited from time to time However this becomes a supervisory task when the mark is used in a franchise agreement for the sale of goods or services carrying the reputation of the mark For a franchise it is said a fee is paid even though it comprises a royalty element To be a franchise the agreement must be a composite of the items the right to use a trade mark to offer sell or distribute goods or services the trademark element payment of a required royalty or fee the fee element significant assistance or control with respect to the franchisee s business the supervisory element dd One of the above three items must not apply for the franchise agreement to be considered a trade mark agreement and its laws and conventions In a franchise for which there is no convention laws apply concerning training brand support operating systems support and technical support in a written format Disclosure CopyrightCopyright law gives the owner the right to prevent others from copying creating derivative works or using their works Copyrights like patent rights can be divided in many different ways by the right implicated by specific geographic or market territories or by more specific criteria Each may be the subject of a separate license and royalty arrangements Copyright royalties are often very specific to the nature of work and field of endeavor With respect to music royalties for performance rights in the United States are set by the Library of Congress Copyright Royalty Board Performance rights to recordings of a performance are usually managed by one of several performance rights organizations Payments from these organizations to performing artists are known as residuals and performance royalties Royalty free music provides more direct compensation to the artists In 1999 recording artists formed the Recording Artists Coalition to repeal supposedly technical revisions to American copyright statutes which would have classified all sound recordings as works for hire effectively assigning artists copyrights to record labels Book authors may sell their copyright to the publisher Alternatively they might receive as a royalty a certain amount per book sold It is common in the UK for example for authors to receive a 10 royalty on book sales Some photographers and musicians may choose to publish their works for a one time payment This is known as a royalty free license Book publishingAll book publishing royalties are paid by the publisher who determines an author s royalty rate except in rare cases in which the author can demand high advances and royalties For most cases the publishers advance an amount part of the royalty which can constitute the bulk of the author s total income plus whatever little flows from the running royalty stream Some costs may be attributed to the advance paid which depletes further advances to be paid or from the running royalty paid The author and the publisher can independently draw up the agreement that binds them or alongside an agent representing the author There are many risks for the author definition of cover price the retail price net price the discounts on the sale the bulk sales on the POD publish on demand platform the term of the agreement audit of the publishers accounts in case of impropriety etc which an agent can provide The following illustrates the income to an author on the basis chosen for royalty particularly in POD which minimizes losses from inventory and is based on computer technologies Book publishing Royalties Net and Retail Compared Retail Basis Net BasisCover Price 15 00 15 00Discount to Booksellers 50 50 Wholesale Price 7 50 7 50Printing Cost 200 pp Book 3 50 3 50Net Income 4 00 4 00Royalty Rate 20 20 Royalty Calcn 0 20x15 0 20x4Royalty 3 00 0 80 dd dd dd Hardback royalties on the published price of trade books usually range from 10 to 12 5 with 15 for more important authors On paperback it is usually 7 5 to 10 going up to 12 5 only in exceptional cases All the royalties displayed below are on the cover price Paying 15 to the author can mean that the other 85 of the cost pays for editing and proof reading printing and binding overheads and the profits if any to the publisher The publishing company pays no royalty on bulk purchases of books since the buying price may be a third of the cover price sold on a singles basis Unlike the UK the United States does not specify a maximum retail price for books that serves as base for calculation Based on net receipts Methods of calculating royalties changed during the 1980s due to the rise of retail chain booksellers which demanded increasing discounts from publishers As a result rather than paying royalties based on a percentage of a book s cover price publishers preferred to pay royalties based on their net receipts According to The Writers and Artists Yearbook of 1984 under the new arrangement appropriate upward adjustments are of course made to the royalty figure and the arrangement is of no disadvantage to the author Despite this assurance in 1991 Frederick Nolan author and former publishing executive explained that net receipts royalties are often more in the interest of publishers than authors It makes sense for the publisher to pay the author on the basis of what he receives but it by no means makes it a good deal for the author Example 10 000 copies of a 20 book with a 10 percent cover price royalty will earn him 20 000 The same number sold but discounted at 55 percent will net the publisher 90 000 the author s ten percent of that figure yields him 9 000 Which is one reason why publishers prefer net receipts contracts Among the many other advantages to the publisher of such contracts is the fact that they make possible what is called a sheet deal In this the multinational publisher of that same 10 000 copy print run can substantially reduce his printing cost by running on a further 10 000 copies that is to say printing but not binding them and then further profit by selling these sheets at cost price or even lower if he so chooses to subsidiaries or overseas branches then paying the author 10 percent of net receipts from that deal The overseas subsidiaries bind up the sheets into book form and sell at full price for a nice profit to the Group as a whole The only one who loses is the author In 2003 two American authors Ken Englade and Patricia Simpson sued HarperCollins USA successfully for selling their work to its foreign affiliates at improperly high discounts Harper Collins is essentially selling books to itself at discounted rates upon which it then calculates the author s royalty and then Harper Collins shares in the extra profit when the book is resold to the consumer by the foreign affiliates without paying the author any further royalty This forced a class action readjustment for thousands of authors contracted by HarperCollins between November 1993 and June 1999 MusicUnlike other forms of intellectual property music royalties have a strong linkage to individuals composers score songwriters lyrics and writers of musical plays in that they can own the exclusive copyright to created music and can license it for performance independent of corporates Recording companies and the performing artists that create a sound recording of the music enjoy a separate set of copyrights and royalties from the sale of recordings and from their digital transmission depending on national laws With the advent of pop music and major innovations in technology in the communication and presentations of media the subject of music royalties has become complex Art royaltiesResale royalty or droit de suite Art Resale Royalty is a right to a royalty payment upon resales of art works that applies in some jurisdictions Whilst there are currently approximately 60 countries that have some sort of Resale Royalty on their statute books evidence of resale schemes that can be said to be actually operating schemes is restricted to Europe Australia and the American state of California For example in May 2011 the European commissions ec europa webpage on Resale royalty stated that under the heading Indicative list of third countries Article 7 2 A letter was sent to Member States on 1 March 2006 requesting that they provide a list of third countries which meet these requirements and that they also provide evidence of application To date the commission has not been supplied with evidence for any third country which demonstrates that they qualify for inclusion on this list The emphasis is from the European commission web page Apart from placing a levy on the resale of some art like objects there are few common facets to the various national schemes Most schemes prescribe a minimum amount that the artwork must receive before the artist can invoke resale rights usually the hammer price or price Some countries prescribe and others such as Australia do not prescribe the maximum royalty that can be received Most do prescribe the calculation basis of the royalty Some country s make the usage of the royalty compulsory Some country s prescribe a sole monopoly collection service agency while others like the UK and France allow multiple agencies Some schemes involve varying degrees of retrospective application and other schemes such as Australia s are not retrospective at all In some cases for example Germany an openly tax like use is made of the royalties Half of the money collected is redistributed to fund public programs The New Zealand and Canadian governments have not proceeded with any sort of artist resale scheme The Australian scheme does not apply to the first resale of artworks purchased prior to the schemes enactment June 2010 and individual usage of the right by Australian artists is not compulsory In Australia artists have a case by case right under clause 22 23 of the Act to refuse consent to the usage of the right by the appointed collection society and or make their own collection arrangements Details of the Australian scheme can be gotten from the website of the sole appointed Australian agency The Copyright Agency Limited The UK scheme is in the context of common law countries an oddity No other common law country has mandated an individual economic right where actual usage of the right is compulsory for the individual right holder Whether the common law conception of an individual economic right as an individual right of control of usage is compatible with the Code Civil origins of droit de suite is open to question The UK is the largest art resale market where a form of ARR is operating details of how the royalty is calculated as a portion of sale price in the UK can be accessed here DACS In the UK the scheme was in early 2012 extended to all artists still in copyright In most European jurisdictions the right has the same duration as the term of copyright In California law heirs receive royalty for 20 years The royalty applies to any work of graphic or plastic art such as a ceramic collage drawing engraving glassware lithograph painting photograph picture print sculpture tapestry However a copy of a work is not to be regarded as a work unless the copy is one of a limited number made by the artist or under the artist s authority In the UK the resale of a work bought directly from the artist and then resold within 3 years for a value of 10 000 or less is not affected by the royalty The situation as to how ARR applies in situations where an art work is physically made by a person or persons who are not the name artist who first exhibits and sells the work is not clear In particular whilst ARR is inalienable it seems conceivable that in cases where the copyright on an artwork is transferred sold prior to the first sale of an artwork the inalienable ARR right is also effectively sold transferred Whether resale royalties are of net economic benefit to artists is a highly contested area Many economic studies have seriously questioned the assumptions underlying the argument that resale royalties have net benefits to artists Many modelings have suggested that resale royalties could be actually harmful to living artists economic positions Australia s chief advocate for the adoption of artist resale royalties the collection society Viscopy commissioned in 2004 a report from Access Economics to model the likely impact of their scheme In the resulting report Access Economics warned that the claim of net benefit to artists was based upon extremely unrealistic assumptions in particular the assumption that seller and buyer behaviour would be completely unaffected by the introduction of RRR ARR and that Access Economics considers that the results of this analysis are both unhelpful and potentially misleading Software royaltiesThere is simply too much computer software to consider the royalties applicable to each The following is a guide to royalty rates Computer Software 10 5 average 6 8 median Internet 11 7 average 7 5 median For the development of customer specific software one will have to consider Total software development cost Break even cost if the software can be sold to many agencies Ownership of code if the client s he bears the development cost Life of the software usually short or requiring maintenance Risk in development high commanding A high price Other royalty arrangementsThe term royalty also covers areas outside of IP and technology licensing such as oil gas and mineral royalties paid to the owner of a property by a resources development company in exchange for the right to exploit the resource In a business project the promoter financier LHS enabled the transaction but are no longer actively interested may have a royalty right to a portion of the income or profits of the business This sort of royalty is often expressed as a contract right to receive money based on a royalty formula rather than an actual ownership interest in the business In some businesses this sort of royalty is sometimes called an override Alliances and partnerships Royalties may exist in technological alliances and partnerships The latter is more than mere access to secret technical or a trade right to accomplish an objective It is in the last decade of the past century and the first of this one of the major means of technology transfer Its importance for the licensor and the licensee lies in its access to markets and raw materials and labor when the international trend is towards globalization There are three main groups when it comes to technological alliances They are Joint ventures sometimes abbreviated JV the Franchises and Strategic Alliances SA Joint ventures are usually between companies long in contact with a purpose JVs are very formal forms of association and depending on the country where they are situated subject to a rigid code of rules in which the public may or may not have an opportunity to participate in capital partly depending on the size of capital required and partly on Governmental regulations They usually revolve around products and normally involve an inventive step Franchises revolve around services and they are closely connected with trademarks an example of which is McDonald s Although franchises have no convention like trademarks or copyrights they can be mistaken as a trademark copyright in agreements The franchisor has close control over the franchisee which in legal terms cannot be tie ins such as frachisee located in an areas owned by the franchisor Strategic Alliances can involve a project such as bridge building a product or a service As the name implies is more a matter of marriage of convenience when two parties want to associate to take up a particular but modest short term task but generally are uncomfortable with the other But the strategic alliance could be a test of compatibility for the forming of a joint venture company and a precedent step Note that all of these ventures s could be in a third county JVs and franchises are rarely found formed within a county They largely involve third countries On occasion a JV or SA may be wholly oriented to research and development typically involving multiple organizations working on an agreed form of engagement The Airbus is an example of such Technical assistance and service in technology transfer Firms in developing countries often are asked by the supplier of know how or patent licensing to consider technical service TS and technical assistance TA as elements of the technology transfer process and to pay royalty on them TS and TA are associated with the IP intellectual property transferred and sometimes dependent on its acquisition but they are by no means IP TA and TS may also be the sole part of the transfer or the transferor of the IP their concurrent supplier They are seldom met with in the developed countries which sometimes view even know how as similar to TS TS comprises services which are the specialized knowledge of firms or acquired by them for operating a special process It is often a bundle of services which can by itself meet an objective or help in meeting it It is delivered over time at end of which the acquirer becomes proficient to be independent of the service In this process no consideration is given on whether the transfer of the proprietary element has been concluded or not On the other hand technical assistance is a package of assistance given on a short timetable It can range variously from procurement of equipment for a project inspection services on behalf of the buyer the training of buyer s personnel and the supply technical or managerial staff Again TA is independent of IP services The payment for these services is a fee not a royalty The TS fee is dependent on how many of the specialized staff of its supplier are required and over what period of time Sometimes the learning capacity to whom the TS is supplied is involved In any case the cost per service hour should be calculated and evaluated Note that in selecting a TS supplier often the IP supplier experience and dependency are critical In the case of TA there is usually a plurality of firms and choice is feasible Approaches to royalty rateIntellectual property This section does not cite any sources Please help improve this section by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed September 2008 Learn how and when to remove this message The rate of royalty applied in a given case is determined by various factors the most notable of which are Market drivers and demand structure Territorial extent of rights Exclusivity of rights Level of innovation and stage of development see The Technology Life Cycle Sustainability of the technology Degree and competitive availability of other technologies Inherent risk Strategic need The portfolio of rights negotiated Fundability Deal reward structure negotiation strength To correctly gauge royalty rates the following criteria must be taken into consideration The transaction is at arms length There is a willing buyer and a willing seller The transaction is not under compulsionRate determination and illustrative royalties This section does not cite any sources Please help improve this section by adding citations to reliable sources Unsourced material may be challenged and removed September 2008 Learn how and when to remove this message There are three general approaches to assess the applicable royalty rate in the licensing of intellectual property They are The Cost Approach The Comparable Market Approach The Income Approach For a fair evaluation of the royalty rate the relationship of the parties to the contract should be at arms length related parties such as the subsidiary and the parent company need to transact as though they were independent parties be viewed as acting free and without compulsionCost approach The Cost Approach considers the several elements of cost that may have been entered to create the intellectual property and to seek a royalty rate that will recapture the expense of its development and obtain a return that is commensurate with its expected life Costs considered could include R amp D expenditures pilot plant and test marketing costs technology upgrading expenses patent application expenditure and the like The method has limited utility since the technology is not priced competitively on what the market can bear principles or in the context of the price of similar technologies More importantly by lacking optimization through additional expense it may earn benefits below its potential However the method may be appropriate when a technology is licensed out during its R amp D phase as happens with venture capital investments or it is licensed out during one of the stages of clinical trials of a pharmaceutical In the former case the venture capitalist obtains an equity position in the company developing the technology in exchange for financing a part of the development cost recovering it and obtaining an appropriate margin when the company gets acquired or it goes public through the IPO route Recovery of costs with opportunity of gain is also feasible when development can be followed stage wise as shown below for a pharmaceutical undergoing clinical trials the licensee pays higher royalties for the product as it moves through the normal stages of its development Success State of development Royalty rates NaturePre clinical success 0 5 in vitroPhase I safety 5 10 100 healthy peoplePhase II efficacy 8 15 300 subjectsPhase III effectiveness 10 20 several thousand patientsLaunched product 20 regulatory body approval A similar approach is used when custom software is licensed an in license i e an incoming license The product is accepted on a royalty schedule depending on the software meeting set stage wise specifications with acceptable error levels in performance tests Comparable market approach Here the cost and the risk of development are disregarded The royalty rate is determined from comparing competing or similar technologies in an industry modified by considerations of useful remaining life of the technology in that industry and contracting elements such as exclusivity provisions front end royalties field of use restrictions geographic limitations and the technology bundle the mix of patents know how trade mark rights etc accompanying it Economist J Gregory Sidak explains that comparable licenses when selected correctly reveal what the licensor and the licensee consider to be fair compensation for the use of the patented technology and thus will most accurately depict the price that a licensee would willingly pay for that technology The Federal Circuit has on numerous occasions confirmed that the comparable market approach is a reliable methodology to calculate a reasonable royalty Although widely used the prime difficulty with this method is obtaining access to data on comparable technologies and the terms of the agreements that incorporate them Fortunately there are several recognized by whom organizations see Royalty Rate Websites listed at the end of this article who have comprehensive citation needed information on both royalty rates and the principal terms of the agreements of which they are a part There are also IP related organizations such as the Licensing Executives Society which enable its members to access and share privately assembled data The two tables shown below are drawn selectively from information that is available with an IP related organization and on line The first depicts the range and distribution of royalty rates in agreements The second shows the royalty rate ranges in select technology sectors latter data sourced from Dan McGavock of IPC Group Chicago USA Royalty Distribution Analysis in Industry Industry Licenses nos Min Royalty Max Royalty Average Median Automotive 35 1 0 15 0 4 7 4 0Computers 68 0 2 15 0 5 2 4 0Consumer Gds 90 0 0 17 0 5 5 5 0Electronics 132 0 5 15 0 4 3 4 0Healthcare 280 0 1 77 0 5 8 4 8Internet 47 0 3 40 0 11 7 7 5Mach Tools 84 0 5 26 5 2 4 6Pharma Bio 328 0 1 40 0 7 0 5 1Software 119 0 0 70 0 10 5 6 8 dd Royalty Rate Segmentation in Some Technology Sectors Industry 0 2 2 5 5 10 10 15 15 20 20 25 Aerospace 50 50 Chemical 16 5 58 1 24 3 0 8 0 4 Computer 62 5 31 3 6 3 Electronics 50 0 25 0 25 0 Healthcare 3 3 51 7 45 0 Pharmaceuticals 23 6 32 1 29 3 12 5 1 1 0 7 Telecom 40 0 37 3 23 6 dd dd Commercial sources also provide information that is invaluable for making comparisons The following table provides typical information that is obtainable for instance from Royaltystat Sample License Parameters dd dd dd dd Reference 7787 Effective Date 1 October 1998 SIC Code 2870 SEC Filed Date 26 July 2005 SEC Filer Eden Bioscience Corp Royalty Rate 2 000 SEC Filing 10 Q Royalty Base Net Sales Agreement Type Patent Exclusive Yes Licensor Cornell Research Foundation Inc Licensee Eden Bioscience Corp Lump Sum Pay Research support is 150 000 for 1 year Duration 17 year s Territory Worldwide Coverage Exclusive patent license to make have made use and sell products incorporating biological materials including genes proteins and peptide fragments expression systems cells and antibodies for the field of plant disease The comparability between transactions requires a comparison of the significant economic conditions that may affect the contracting parties Similarity of geographies Relevant date Same industry Market size and its economic development Contracting or expanding markets Market activity whether wholesale retail other Relative market shares of contracting entities Location specific costs of production and distribution Competitive environment in each geography Fair alternatives to contracting partiesIncome approach The Income approach focuses on the licensor estimating the profits generated by the licensee and obtaining an appropriate share of the generated profit It is unrelated to costs of technology development or the costs of competing technologies The approach requires the licensee or licensor a to generate a cash flow projection of incomes and expenses over the life span of the license under an agreed scenario of incomes and costs b determining the Net Present Value NPV of the profit stream based on a selected discount factor and c negotiating the division of such profit between the licensor and the licensee The NPV of a future income is always lower than its current value because an income in the future is attended by risk In other words an income in the future needs to be discounted in some manner to obtain its present equivalent The factor by which a future income is reduced is known as the discount rate Thus 1 00 received a year from now is worth 0 9091 at a 10 discount rate and its discounted value will be still lower two years down the line The actual discount factor used depends on the risk assumed by the principal gainer in the transaction For instance a mature technology worked in different geographies will carry a lower risk of non performance thus a lower discount rate than a technology being applied for the first time A similar situation arises when there is the option of working the technology in one of two different regions the risk elements in each region would be different The method is treated in greater detail using illustrative data in Royalty Assessment The licensor s share of the income is usually set by the 25 rule of thumb which is said to be even used by tax authorities in the US and Europe for arms length transactions The share is on the operating profit of the licensee firm Even where such division is held contentious the rule can still be the starting point of negotiations Following are three aspects that are important for the profit a the profit that accrues to the licensee may not arise solely through the engine of the technology There are returns from the mix of assets it employs such as fixed and working capital and the returns from intangible assets such as distribution systems trained workforce etc Allowances need to be made for them b profits are also generated by thrusts in the general economy gains from infrastructure and the basket of licensed rights patents trademark know how A lower royalty rate may apply in an advanced country where large market volumes can be commanded or where protection to the technology is more secure than in an emerging economy or perhaps for other reasons the inverse c the royalty rate is only one aspect of the negotiation Contractual provisions such as an exclusive license rights to sub license warranties on the performance of technology etc may enhance the advantages to the licensee which is not compensated by the 25 metric The basic advantage of this approach which is perhaps the most widely applied is that the royalty rate can be negotiated without comparative data on how other agreements have been transacted In fact it is almost ideal for a case where precedent does not exist It is perhaps relevant to note that the IRS also uses these three methods in modified form to assess the attributable income or division of income from a royalty based transaction between a US company and its foreign subsidiary since US law requires that a foreign subsidiary pay an appropriate royalty to the parent company Other compensation modes Royalties are only one among many ways of compensating owners for use of an asset Others include buying the asset outright possibly with a leaseback arrangement offering the licensor an equity position in the licensee company staged milestone payments as in drug development and commissioned software arrangements lump sum payment made to the licensor in one or more installments cross licensing agreements with or without cash payments and entering into a strategic alliance or Joint Venture In discussing the licensing of Intellectual Property the terms valuation and evaluation need to be understood in their rigorous terms Evaluation is the process of assessing a license in terms of the specific metrics of a particular negotiation which may include its circumstances the geographical spread of licensed rights product range market width licensee competitiveness growth prospects etc On the other hand valuation is the fair market value FMV of the asset trademark patent or know how at which it can be sold between a willing buyer and willing seller in the context of best awareness of circumstances The FMV of the IP where assessable may itself be a metric for evaluation If an emerging company is listed on the stock market the market value of its intellectual property can be estimated from the data of the balance sheet using the equivalence Market Capitalization Net Working capital Net Fixed assets Routine Intangible assets IP where the IP is the residual after deducting the other components from the market valuation of the stock One of the most significant intangibles may be the work force The method may be quite useful for valuing trademarks of a listed company if it is mainly or the only IP in play franchising companies See alsoCelebrity bond Copyright transfer agreement Payola Revenue based financing Royalty free AuthorShare a system for charging royalties for the second hand sale of books and other media References Focus Tax and Intellectual Property April 2004 Allens Arthur Robinson Archived from the original on 3 September 2007 Retrieved 13 September 2007 Royalty definition law com Archived from the original on 9 March 2012 Retrieved 13 September 2007 United Nations Industrial Development Organization 1996 Manual on Technology Transfer Negotiation Vienna United Nations Industrial Development Organization ISBN 92 1 106302 7 Guidelines for Evaluation of Transfer of Technology Agreements United Nations New York 1979 Licensing Guide for Developing Countries A Guide on the Legal Aspects of the Negotiation and Preparation of Industrial Property Licenses and Technology Transfer Agreements Appropriate to the Needs of Developing Countries Geneva World Intellectual Property Organization 1977 ISBN 92 805 0395 2 UNIDO International Workshop on Technology Transfer Negotiation and Plant Level Technology Needs Assessment 7 8 December 1999 New Delhi Dave Tyrrell Intellectual Property amp Licensing Vertex Archived from the original on 23 March 2019 Retrieved 14 September 2007 Royalty interest definition Schlumberger Archived from the original on 29 June 2006 Retrieved 13 September 2007 Calculating Royalty Indigenous and Northern Affairs Canada 2010 Retrieved 12 July 2018 Archived copy Archived from the original on 17 July 2018 Retrieved 10 September 2021 a href wiki Template Cite web title Template Cite web cite web a CS1 maint archived copy as title link CS1 maint bot original URL status unknown link oilgas1031 com oilgas1031 com Archived from the original on 6 April 2013 Retrieved 4 May 2013 Sell Gas Royalty Sell Oil Royalty Sell Mineral Rights amp Royalties broadmoorminerals com Archived from the original on 27 November 2013 Retrieved 27 November 2013 Types of Wind Royalties Blue Mesa Minerals Retrieved 7 August 2023 J Gregory Sidak Ongoing Royalties for Patent Infringement 24 TEX INTELL PROP L J at 6 forthcoming 2016 Archived from the original on 24 August 2017 Retrieved 4 February 2016 https scholarlycommons law wlu edu cgi viewcontent cgi article 4304 amp context wlulr bare URL Lance Wyatt Keeping Up with the Game The Use of the Nash Bargaining Solution in Patent Infringement Cases 31 Santa Clara High Tech L J 427 2015 Available at http digitalcommons law scu edu chtlj vol31 iss3 2 Georgia Pacific Corp v U S Plywood Corp 318 F Supp 1116 1116 S D N Y 1970 modified sub nom Georgia Pacific Corp v U S Plywood Champion Papers Inc 446 F 2d 295 2d Cir 1971 Georgia pacific Corporation Appellant v U S Plywood champion Papers Inc Appellee 446 F 2d 295 2d Cir 1971 Justia Law This article incorporates text from this source which is in the public domain Patent Infringement Damages Expert Witness Georgia Pacific Factors No World Borders Experts in healthcare J Gregory Sidak Ongoing Royalties for Patent Infringement 24 TEX INTELL PROP L J at 14 forthcoming 2016 Archived from the original on 24 August 2017 Retrieved 4 February 2016 Ranges of royalty rates and royalty guidelines U S Pharmaceutical Industry Archived from the original on 28 September 2007 Retrieved 19 July 2007 Licensing Economics Review The Royalty Rate Journal of Intellectual Property December 2002 p 8 Sample License Parameters Archived from the original on 13 April 2008 Retrieved 26 October 2007 J Gregory Sidak 2014 The Proper Royalty Base for Patent Damages 10 J COMPETITION L amp ECON 989 990 criterioneconomics com Archived from the original on 30 October 2015 Retrieved 20 October 2015 Mallat Chibli Joint ventures in Lebanese and European law mallat com Archived from the original on 14 June 2011 Retrieved 29 November 2010 DHL Corporation and Subsidiaries vs Commissioner of Internal Revenue Docket Nos 19570 95 26103 95 United States Tax Court PDF Archived from the original PDF on 7 March 2008 Retrieved 9 September 2007 Four little words 28 August 2000 Archived from the original on 13 January 2010 Retrieved 15 March 2007 Don Henley Speaks on Behalf of Recording Artists Archived from the original on 17 January 2006 Retrieved 15 March 2007 The Writers and Artists Yearbook 1984 p 422 Malcolm v Oxford Fred Nolan www akmedea com Archived from the original on 5 January 2016 Retrieved 5 January 2016 Casetext casetext com Archived from the original on 5 January 2016 Retrieved 5 January 2016 Englade amp Simpson vs HarperCollins www akmedea com Archived from the original on 4 March 2016 Retrieved 5 January 2016 Internal Market amp raquo Copyright amp raquo Resale Right European Commission The EU Single Market Archived from the original on 27 January 2012 Retrieved 12 December 2011 About the artists resale royalty scheme resaleroyalty org au Archived from the original on 25 February 2011 Retrieved 29 November 2010 Kirstein R Schmidtchen D 2001 Do Artists Benefit from Resale Royalties An Economic Analysis of a New EU Directive In Deffains B Kirat T eds Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries The Economics of Legal Relationships Vol 6 Elsevier Science Amsterdam et al 231 248 Viscopy Access Economics PDF Retrieved 29 November 2010 dead link Royalty Rates Software Development Profit Sharing Royalty Rates Options Northwest Data Solutions Archived from the original on 28 November 2018 Retrieved 28 November 2018 Manual on Technology Transfer Negotiation A reference for policy makers and practitioners on Technology Transfer 1996 United Nations Industrial Development Organization Vienna 1990 ISBN 92 1 106302 7 Patterns of Internationalization for Developing Country Enterprises United Nations Industrial Organization Vienna Austria 2008 ISBN 978 92 1 106443 8 Manual on Technology Transfer Negotiation A reference for policy makers and practitioners on Technology Transfer 1996 United Nations Industrial Development Organization Vienna 1990 ISBN 92 1 106302 7 pp 260 261 J Gregory Sidak Apportionment FRAND Royalties and Comparable Licenses After Ericsson v D Link 2016 U Ill L REV forthcoming Archived from the original on 17 March 2016 Retrieved 5 February 2016 Ericsson Inc v D Link Systems Inc 773 F 3d 1201 Fed Cir 2014 LaserDynamics Inc v Quanta Comput Inc 694 F 3d 51 Fed Cir 2012 Jarosz John Mulhern Carla December 2002 Use Of The 25 Per Cent Rule In Valuing IP Archived from the original on 12 September 2009 Retrieved 20 September 2007 David G Weiler Valuing Your Intellectual Property for Strategic Alliances and Financing Archived from the original on 13 November 2006 Retrieved 20 September 2007 Sample License Parameters Archived from the original on 8 December 2006 Retrieved 26 September 2007 Treasury Evaluations Archived from the original on 20 September 2007 Retrieved 27 September 2007 External linksLibrary resources about Royalties Resources in your library Quotations related to Royalty payment at Wikiquote Royalty Rate Websites CPT page on Royalties on patents for health care inventions